Author's Accepted Manuscript
Manufacturer-remanufacturing vs Supplier-remanufacturing in a Closed-loop Supply Chain
Yu Xiong, Quanwu Zhao, Yu Zhou
www.elsevier.comlocate/iipe
PII: S0925-5273(16)00065-7
DOI: http ://dx.doi. org/ 10.1016/j .ijpe.2016.03.001
Reference: PROECO6358
To appear in: Intern. Journal of Production Economics
Received date: 8 December 2014 Revised date : 17 July 2015 Accepted date: 22 February 2016
Cite this article as: Yu Xiong, Quanwu Zhao and Yu Zhou, Manufacturer-remanufacturing vs Supplier-remanufacturing in a Closed-loop Supply Chain Intern. Journal of Production Economics
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.ijpe.2016.03.001
This is a PDF file of an unedited manuscript that has been accepted fo publication. As a service to our customers we are providing this early version o the manuscript. The manuscript will undergo copyediting, typesetting, an< review of the resulting galley proof before it is published in its final citable form Please note that during the production process errors may be discovered whic could affect the content, and all legal disclaimers that apply to the journal pertain
Manufacturer-remanufacturing vs Supplier-remanufacturing in a Closed-loop Supply Chain
Yu Xiong1, Quanwu Zhao2, Yu Zhou2*
1 Newcastle Business School, Northumbria University, Newcastle, NE1 8ST, UK
2 School of Economics and Business Administration, Chongqing University, 174
Shazhengjie, Chongqing, 400044, P.R. China
*Corresponding author. Tel: 0086 13883305292.
E-mail addresses: yu.xiong@northumbria.ac.uk (Y. Xiong),
zhaoquanwumx@cqu.edu.cn (Q. Zhao), zhouyu@cqu.edu.cn (Y. Zhou).
Remanufacturing at the component level could be performed by either a manufacturer or a supplier. In this paper, we analyze the performance of manufacturer-remanufacturing and supplier-remanufacturing in a decentralized closed-loop supply chain, and examine their desirability from different stakeholder perspectives. We find that the manufacturer may engage in remanufacturing of used components even if remanufacturing is costlier than traditional manufacturing; given remanufacturing is costlier, the manufacturer may forgo remanufacturing due to a marginal increase in consumer willingness-to-pay for the remanufactured product. If the unit remanufacturing cost is high enough, the manufacturer and consumers prefer manufacturer-remanufacturing, while the supplier and the environment prefer supplier-remanufacturing; otherwise, the manufacturer, the supplier, and consumers prefer supplier-remanufacturing, while the environment's preference is contingent on the environmental impact discount for the remanufactured product. Finally, the key findings are distilled into a roadmap to guide the development of remanufacturing.
Keywords: supply chain management; remanufacturing; environmental
performance
1. Introduction
In recent years, executives around the world are rallying behind sustainability, and have experienced a dramatic increase of interest in remanufacturing. Successful examples from many industries show that remanufacturing can be both faster-growing and more profitable than traditional manufacturing (Ayres et al. 1997, Guide and Wassenhove 2003, Geyer et al. 2007). However, the remanufacturability of used products as a whole is restricted by increasing technical complexity, shorted product life cycle, rising costs and uncertainties.
Remanufacturing at the component level is an alternative that may help maximize the revenue generated from the return stream (Fleischmann et al. 2003), which has been a consensus between researchers and managers. In theory, remanufacturing is defined as "a production strategy whose goal is to recover the residual value of used products by reusing components that are still functioning well" (Debo et al. 2005). In practice, the remanufacturing process of Caterpillar (2010) can be briefly described as:
• First, used products collected from customers are disassembled into their constituent components;
• Next, the individual components are remanufactured to exact specifications to ensure they provide the same quality, reliability and durability as they did when they ware new;
• Last, remanufactured components are assembled, tested and made ready for sale as the remanufactured product.
In addition, nowadays, few manufacturers rely on only themselves to design and produce the whole product, which implies that most components are provided by
their suppliers. Thus, remanufacturing at the component level can be performed by manufacturers such as Caterpillar, or by their key component suppliers. In 2008, Chinese National Development and Reform Commission launched a pilot program of auto part remanufacturing, and 14 firms were selected and supported to start up remanufacturing, seven of which are auto manufacturers (or their subsidiaries) and the other seven are part suppliers (Sina 2008).
Thus, a research question is naturally emerging: what is the difference between manufacturer-remanufacturing and supplier-remanufacturing? Our primary objective in this paper is to develop a general understanding of the desirability of manufacturer-remanufacturing and supplier-remanufacturing from different stakeholder perspectives.
The literature on managing the closed-loop supply chain with remanufacturing is abundant, we refer the reader to Atasu et al. (2008a), Guide and Van Wassenhove (2009), and Souza (2013) for a thorough discussion. It has been demonstrated that remanufacturing can be an effective marketing strategy for manufacturers to defend their market share and render a higher profit (Heese et al. 2005, Atasu et al. 2008, Chen and Chang 2013, Wu 2015). However, to the best of our knowledge, few papers consider the possibility of supplier-remanufacturing and identify the "right" remanufacturer, especially from the perspectives of the consumers and the environment. Xiong et al. (2013) make the first attempt to analyze how the interaction between the manufacturer and the supplier on new product production influences to the economic and environmental performance of remanufacturing. We extend Xiong et al. (2013)'s model to analyze and compare the implications of manufacturer-remanufacturing and supplier-remanufacturing.
More importantly, our model deviates from the literature by allowing remanufacturing a used component does not cost less than manufacturing a new one. On one hand, this deviation is greatly motivated by the industrial practice: although some pioneers have made a profit, most manufacturers have no infrastructure and expertise to remanufacture in a profitable manner (Ferguson 2010). Specifically, in
the globalized world today, remanufacturing is still largely a local business because many countries prohibit the international trade of used products. Huawei, the world's third largest cell phone producer, capitalizes on recycling in Europe, but does not remanufacture (Huawei 2015). This may be driven by the possibility that producing a remanufactured cell phone in Europe costs more than producing a new one in China. On the other hand, this derivation leads us to some very interesting findings on firms' remanufacturing strategy. The prior literature on remanufacturing typically defaults that remanufacturing costs less than traditional manufacturing, e.g., in a seminal research, Ferrer and Swaminathan (2006) use the remanufacturing savings as the key parameter to define the strategy space. To the best of our knowledge, only one paper, Caner et al. (2013), considers the situation where remanufacturing is costlier for an integrated manufacturer. However, it finds remanufacturing is seldom profitable in this situation and suggests the manufacturer focus on situations where remanufacturing costs less. In contrast, our work demonstrates the manufacturer could be better off by engaging in remanufacturing even if it costs more than manufacturing in a decentralized supply chain. In addition, given remanufacturing is costlier, the analytical result shows that the manufacturer may decide to forgo remanufacturing as a result of a marginal increase in consumer willingness-to-pay for the remanufactured product. These findings make an excellent complement to the current literature on remanufacturing.
The rest of this paper is organized as follows. Section 2 delineates our modeling assumptions and notation. Section 3 presents the analysis and solutions of two models with manufacturer-remanufacturing and supplier-remanufacturing, respectively. Section 4 discusses firms' remanufacturing strategy and identifies the "right" remanufacturer from different stakeholder perspectives. Section 5 concludes this paper. Appendixes contains the detailed proofs of all propositions. Hereinafter, for convenience, we use pronouns 'she' and 'he' to refer to the supplier and the manufacturer, respectively.
2. Assumptions and notation
We consider an industry with only one product but two versions: the new product and the remanufactured product. To focus our attention on the desirability of manufacturer-remanufacturing and supplier-remanufacturing from different stakeholder perspectives, we consider a simple bilateral monopoly, as depicted in Figures 1 and 2. In this paper, we do not consider the reverse channel choice, which has been widely studied in the existing literature, e.g., Xiong et al. (2014), Hong et al. (2015), and Wei et al. (2015). Therefore, it is reasonable to assume that used products are collected (by the retailer, or the manufacturer, or the third-party operator) at a constant cost, which is normalized to 0 .
Figure 1. The closed-loop supply chain model with manufacturer-remanufacturing
Figure 2. The closed-loop supply chain model with supplier-remanufacturing
To isolate the strategic issue of remanufacturing, our model rules out the distortion due to efficiency variance by assuming that either the manufacturer or the supplier costs cr to remanufacture a used component. Similar assumptions have
been widely used in the literature, e.g., Savaskan et al. (2004) assume a manufacturer and a retailer incur a same cost to collect used products, and demonstrate the retailer-managed collection is always preferred by the manufacturer; Zhou et al. (2013) assume centralization and decentralization within a manufacturer are equivalent in terms of the cost structure, and find decentralization outperforms centralization under certain conditions. For the sake of clarity, we assume that, except for the cost to obtain the new/remanufactured component, the manufacturer's other operating costs are constant and normalized to 0 .
Other key assumptions concerning consumer preference, environmental performance, and decision-making rule are borrowed from the literature on closed-loop supply chain management, e.g., Galbreth et al. (2013), Xiong et al. (2013), Chang et al. (2015), and Gu et al. (2015). Here, we present the following set of assumptions, but skip the detailed discussion on their justification. For convenience, Table 1 summarizes the notation used in the model.
Table 1. Notation
Symbol Definition
Cr The unit production cost of the new/remanufactured component
qr The production quantity of the new/remanufactured product
Pn , Pr The market clearing price of the new/remanufactured product
Wr The wholesale price of the new/remanufactured component
The consumer value discount for the remanufactured product
* The environmental impact discount for the remanufactured product
The player i 's profit in scenario k of the model of j
The consumer surplus in scenario k of the model of j
The supply chain's environmental performance in scenario k of the model of j
Assumption 1. The inverse demand functions for new and remanufactured products are
Pn =1 - qn ~sQr, Pr =s(1 - qn - q).
Assumption 1 implies that the consumer willingness-to-pay for the new
product is heterogeneous and distributed over the interval [0,1] with the density of
1; each consumer's willingness-to-pay for the remanufactured product is a fraction
S e (0,1) of that for the new one; and each customer buys at most one product that
offers the most utility, as long as the net utility is positive. Thus, the linear inverse demand functions, Equations (1) and (2), can be derived from consumers' utility functions.
Assumption 2. The weighted production quantity of new products and remanufactured products qn + (j)qr is used as a proxy of the closed-loop supply
chain's environmental performance.
It is broadly agreed that the process of remanufacturing has less negative impact on the environmental. Assumption 2 implies that the life-cycle environmental impact of one unit remanufactured product is a fraction ( e (0,1) of that of one unit
new product. Therefore, the closed-loop supply chain' environmental performance is equal to one unit new product's life-cycle environmental impact multiplied by the weighted production quantity of new products and remanufactured products. Regardless of the value of environmental impact, qn + (qr can be a proxy.
Assumption 3. All decisions are considered in a steady-state period: the supplier moves first to price the new component (and the remanufactured component), and then the manufacturer responds by determining the production quantity of new and remanufactured products.
Closed-loop supply chain management is a typical multiple-period problem because new products are used for a certain period and then become cores for remanufacturing. The steady-state period model implies that players use the same policy in every period after the ramp-up in the first period in an infinite horizon setting. It enables us to analytically address our research question without the distraction of initial and terminal time-period effect. Thus, in our model, by assuming that each product can be used for one period and remanufactured at most once, the production quantity of remanufactured products in the current period is bounded by the production quantity of new products in the previous period, which is equal to the
production quantity of new products in the current period, i.e., qr < qn. Admittedly, not all used products could be collected; in practice, we have qr < zqn, t e [0,1].
However, assuming t = 1 in this paper does not change any of qualitative insights.
In addition, we assume that the manufacturer and the supplier are risk-neutral and profit seeking, and have perfect knowledge of the demand and cost information -a reasonable assumption in the steady-state period model. In order to guarantee the market demand of new and remanufactured products is non-negative, our model
requires cM < 1 and cr <5.
In the following analysis, we call the firm who performs remanufacturing as
the remanufacturer; subscript i e {M, S} refers to the manufacturer and the supplier,
respectively; superscript j e {M, S} manufacturer-remanufacturing and supplier-remanufacturing, respectively. The firms' strategic decisions are analysed
under various scenarios, which are distinguished by parameters cn, cr, and S . Subscript k g {1,2,3} indicates the scenario under which our analysis is proceeding.
3. Models and solutions
3.1 The model of manufacturer-remanufacturing
In this subsection, we analyze the model of manufacturer-remanufacturing, in which the suppliers supplies only the new component to the manufacturer. The supplier's and the manufacturer's profit functions can be written as
nÎf =(^ -c)qn,
nf =(Pn (<qn,qr )-^n)qn + (Pr (qn,)-c )qr ,s.t., 0 < qr < qn. (4)
The interaction between the supplier and the manufacturer can be analyzed using backward induction. For a given wn, the manufacturer determines qn and q
to maximize his profit. The optimal production quantity decisions are characterized by the following proposition.
PROPOSITION 1. In the model of manufacturer-remanufacturing, the manufacturer's optimal production quantity decision with respect to the supplier's new component wholesale price is
(i) qf =(1 -w„)/2, qf = 0, if wn <cr/S;
(ii) qf =(1 - Wn -S + cr )/2 (1 -S), qf =(SWn - cr )/2S(l-S), if cjS < wn < (cr + Scr + S - S2 2S ;
(iii) qf = qf =(1 -w„ +S-cr)/2(1 + 3S), if wn >(cr +Scr +S-S2)/2S. Next, when setting wn, the supplier does so with anticipation that the
manufacturer will respond as above. Since the manufacturer's optimal response is
contingent on the value of wn, the process to derive the supplier's optimal new
component wholesale price consists of two steps: (1) we analyze the scenario in which the supplier induces the manufacturer to choose a certain decision; and then (2) we identify the optimal solution by comparing the supplier's profit in all scenarios.
For parsimony we restrict our following analysis to the case of ô < 2/3 . The optimal new component wholesale price for the case of ô > 2/3 is available in the Proof of
Proposition 2, which is a simplification of that for the case of ô < 2/3 .
PROPOSITION 2. In the model of manufacturer-remanufacturing, the supplier's optimal new component wholesale price is
(i) wM =(1+c„)/2, ifcr >cM;
(ii) = cr Ô, if cM < cr < cM;
(iii) W2-2 = (1+cn - ô+cr )/2, if cM < cr < cM ;
(iv) WM3 =(1 + cn +ô-c)/2, if cr <cM; here, ¿M =ô(l + cn)/2,
c3 =1 c
(c. + Sc. + 2S2 -1 -S + VÄ)/2S,
= 8(1 + -0)1(2-8), A = 1 - 2cn + cn2 + 28 - 48c + 28c„2 + 382 + 682c„ - 382c„2. It is worth noting that, the supplier has taken the manufacturer's optimal response into account when setting wn. So, if the supplier's optimal decision is w}
then the manufacturer's optimal decision must be {q^,qM}. Substituting these
optimal decisions back into Equations (3) and (4) gives the supplier's and the manufacturer's profits, as shown in Table 2.
Table 2. The profit expressions in the model of manufacturer-remanufacturing
c £ cm
cm < cr < cm
4' < cr < cm
c. > c
8 (1 + 3S)
8 (1 -S)
(S-cr )( cr-Sc. ) (1 - c„ )2
(1 -c„ -cr + S)2 16 (1 + 3S)
16S(1 -S)
(1 - c ) 16
Note: X = 3cn2 -2S(1 + cr -S)cn +(4-3S)cr2 -6S(1 -S)cr + S + 2S2 -3S3.
3.2 The model of supplier-remanufacturing
In the model of supplier-remanufacturing, the supplier supplies both the new and the remanufactured components to the manufacturer. Their profit functions are
n? = (wn - c ) qn + (wr - ^) qr, (5)
nSM = (pn(q.,)-wn)q.+{pAqn,)-wr)qr,s.t., 0<qr <qn. (6)
Following from Equation's (4) and (6), we have, replacing cr in the manufacturer's profit function in the model of manufacturer-remanufacturing with wr gives his profit function in the model of supplier-remanufacturing. Thus,
intuitively, replacing cr in Proposition 1 with wr gives the manufacturer's optimal
production quantity decision in the model of supplier-remanufacturing.
Similarly, we identify the supplier's optimal decision in two steps, as follows. PROPOSITION3. In the model of supplier-remanufacturing, the supplier's optimal wholesale prices for new and remanufactured components are
(i) wf, = (1 + c„)/2, . wS1 =S(1 + c„)/2., if cr >c?;
(ii) w?2 = (1 + c„)/2, w?2 =(S + cr )/2, if 4 < cr < c?;
(iii) wl = (1 + 4S - S2 + (1 + S) (c„ + cr ))/2 (1 + 3S),
w?3 =S(2S + c„ + cT)/(1 + 3S), if cr <c?; here, c? =Scn,
c2s =S( 2cn +S-1)/(1 + S).
Substituting these optimal decisions back into Equations (5) and (6) gives the supplier's and the manufacturer's profits, as shown in Table 3.
Table 3. The profit expressions in the model of supplier-remanufacturing
4 < 0 < 0s
(1 - c„ - cr + S)2 8(1 + 3S)
(1 -cw -cr + S)2 16(1 + 3S)
Note: Y = Scn2 -2S(1 + cr-S)cn + cr2 +Ô-Ô2
Y (1 - Cn )2
8S (1 -S) 8
16S (1 -S)
(1 - Cn )2 16
4. Comparison and discussion 4.1 Whether to remanufacture
In this subsection, we examine the decision on whether to remanufacturing. Substituting the optimal wholesale price(s) in Propositions 2 and 3 back into the manufacturer's optimal response function gives the production quantity of new and remanufactured products. We say the remanufacturer decides to engage in
remanufacturing if > 0. It is easy to get the following Corollaries.
COROLLARY 1. In the model of manufacturer-remanufacturing, there exists a
threshold value c^ such that the manufacturer should engage in remanufacturing if
cr < c^ ; the threshold value c^ > cM if cn < S/2.
COROLLARY 2. In the model of supplier-remanufacturing, there exists a threshold value cf such that the supplier should engage in remanufacturing if
cr < cf ; the threshold value cf < cw.
Corollaries 1 and 2 shows that in both models, the impact of the remanufacturing cost cr on the decision of whether to remanufacture is monotone,
i.e., the lower the value of cr is, the more likely the remanufacturer is to engage in remanufacturing. What is more interesting and important, we find that the
manufacturer may engage in remanufacturing even if remanufacturing a used component costs more than manufacturing a new one. The economic intuition behind this finding is explained as follows. The supplier measures the cost savings from
remanufacturing by comparing cr and cn, thus, she may remanufacture used components only if cr < cn. By contrast, the manufacturer measures the cost savings by comparing cr and wn. A profit seeking supplier must set wn > cn. Thus, it may be profitable for the manufacturer to remanufacture used components if c < cr < wn.
Next, we can rewrite Propositions 2 and 3 using the consumer value discount for the remanufactured product S as the separating parameter. Thus, following from
Corollaries 1 and 2, and letting cr = c^ (cr = cf ), we have S = (l + cn + cr ± л/В^/2
( S = cr/cn ), В = 1 + 2c + 2cc + cn2 - 6cr + cr2. The impact of S on the decision of
whether to remanufacture is followed.
COROLLARY 3. In the model of manufacturer-remanufacturing, there exists
two threshold values S^ =(l + cn + cr -4B)j2 and S^ =(l + cn + cr +JBy2
such that the manufacturer should engage in remanufacturing if SM <S <S^ ; the
threshold value SSf < 1 if cr > cn.
COROLLARY 4. In the model of supplier-remanufacturing, there exists a threshold value Sf = cjcn such that the supplier should engage in remanufacturing
if S > Sf ; the threshold value Sf > 1 if cr > cn.
Corollaries 3 and 4 shows that in both models, the impact of S on the decision of whether to remanufacture is monotone if cr < cn, i.e., the higher the value of S is, the more likely the remanufacturer is to engage in remanufacturing. But, if cr > cn, although the supplier should not remanufacture any used component, the impact of S on the manufacturer's decision of remanufacturing is non-monotone,
i.e., as the value of 8 increases, at first, the manufacturer is more likely to engage in remanufacturing, but eventually, the manufacturer is more likely to forgo remanufacturing.
This finding is striking because it challenges the generally accepted notion that consumers' low willingness-to-pay for the remanufactured product is a major barrier for remanufacturing (Liu et al. 2009, Atasu et al. 2010, Abbey et al. 2014). In order to understand the counterintuitive finding, let's revisit the interaction between the supplier and the manufacturer in the model of manufacturer-remanufacturing where remanufacturing is profitable if the consumer value discount for the remanufactured product is not low enough and the remanufactured component will cannibalize the supplier's new component sales. If the value of 8 is moderate, the potential cannibalization problem is not serious, and then the supplier is better off by accommodating remanufacturing, e.g., pricing the new component at
wf_2 = (l + cw - 8 + cr)/2; however, if the value of 8 is high, and then the supplier is
better off by changing her strategy to successfully thwart remanufacturing, e.g.,
pricing the new component at w^ = cr/8. As a result, taking the supplier's strategic
behavior into account, the manufacturer's decision on whether to remanufacture may switch from engaging in to forgoing as the increasing of 8 .
4.2 Who is the "right" remanufacturer?
In this subsection, we identify the "right" remanufacturer from different stakeholder perspectives. Following from Propositions 2 and 3, we have six scenarios to examine the desirability of manufacturer-remanufacturing and supplier-remanufacturing, as shown in Table 4 and illustrated in Figure 3. Here, we list only the supplier's optimal
decision in each scenario. As said before, if the supplier's optimal decision is wfk or \wSnk, wSrk}, then the manufacturer's optimal response must be \qlnk,qlrk}. It is worth noting that, the solid line in Figure 3 refers to cr = cf, which separates the
manufacturer's, the consumers' and the environment's preferences to manufacturer-remanufacturing and supplier-remanufacturing, as demonstrated by the following Propositions.
Table 4. These six scenarios of comparison Scenario Condition W \wsn, wsr J
1 c, > cm WM K W}
2 cM < c < cM w^ K w}
3 CM < c,. < cm < 2 ■ {<, W}
4 C1S < c, < cM wM (W„ W j
5 c! < c, < cS w3 { wL wsr2 j
6 c < 4 W3 {wL wS3}
Figure 3. The illustration of these six scenarios
In line with intuition, if the remanufacturing cost is sufficiently low cr < cf
or sufficiently high cr > cf, all used products or no used product will be
remanufactured in both models, and then manufacturer-remanufacturing and supplier-remanufacturing are equivalent from the perspective of all stakeholders (as shown in Proofs of Propositions 4 - 7). Thus, in what follows, we focus on the
scenarios under the condition cf < cr < cf, i.e., Scenarios 2 - 5.
From the perspective of the manufacturer, we identify the "right" remanufacturer as the firm who makes the manufacturer obtain a higher profit. Thus, by comparing the manufacturer's profits in models of manufacturer-remanufacturing and supplier-remanufacturing, we have the following proposition.
PROPOSITION 4. From the perspective of the manufacturer,
manufacturer-remanufacturing is preferred if cr > cf ; otherwise,
supplier-remanufacturing is preferred.
Following from Equation's (4) and (6), letting the supplier remanufacture, the manufacturer's cost to obtain a unit remanufactured component will change from cr
to w ; in addition, a profit seeking supplier must price wr higher than cr. Well,
why does the manufacturer still benefit from supplier-remanufacturing if the remanufacturing cost is low enough? The economic intuition behind Proposition 4 lies
in that, if c < cf, remanufacturing is so profitable that the manufacturer is willing to
remanufacture all used products, and then new and remanufactured products exhibit the characteristics of complements (Debo et al. 2005, Xiong et al. 2013). Therefore, the supplier can appropriate the remanufacturing benefit by pricing the new component higher, which leads to a smaller optimal production quantity of new and remanufactured products and consequently, makes manufacturer-remanufacturing less attractive for the manufacturer. By contrast, with supplier-remanufacturing, although the cost to obtain a unit remanufactured component is higher, the manufacturer can
obtain a lower wholesale price for the new component, e.g., wf > wSn2. So
supplier-remanufacturing is more desirable for the manufacturer if the remanufacturing cost is low enough.
Similarly, from the perspective of the supplier, the "right" remanufacturer is identified as follows.
PROPOSITION 5. From the perspective of the supplier, supplier-remanufacturing is always preferred over manufacturer-remanufacturing.
Proposition 5 shows that manufacturer-remanufacturing is always detrimental to the supplier. The economic intuition behind this result is straightforward. On one
hand, if c > cf, the remanufactured component is a substitute for the new
component, then manufacture-remanufacturing will cannibalize the sales of the new
component and hurt the supplier. On the other hand, if cr < cf, with
manufacturer-remanufacturing, the profit seeking supplier will strategically price the new component higher and the profit seeking manufacturer will strategically produce fewer new products, which forms a loss-loss situation. As a result, manufacturer-remanufacturing is never preferred by the supplier.
From the perspective of the consumers, we identify the "right" remanufacturer as the firm who makes consumers obtain a greater surplus. Based on our linear inverse demand functions, consumer's surplus is calculated as
Comparing the consumers' surpluses in models of manufacturer-remanufacturing and supplier-remanufacturing gives the following proposition.
PROPOSITION 6. From the perspective of the consumers, manufacturer-remanufacturing is preferred if cr > cf ; otherwise, supplier-remanufacturing is preferred.
Following from Propositions 4 and 6, it is revealed that consumers have the
same preference as the manufacturer. This is because, on one hand, if or > of, the
manufacturer will engage in remanufacturing, but the supplier will not, and then remanufacturing drives down the new product price and provides a low-price alternative to the consumers who cannot afford the new product, so
manufacturer-remanufacturing is more preferable; on the other hand, if or < of, as
said before, manufacturer-remanufacturing results in a higher new product price and consequently a lower production quantity, which reduce the consumers' surplus, and then supplier-remanufacturing is naturally more preferable.
It is worth noting that, we use the weighted production quantity qn + (¡)qr as a
proxy of the closed-loop supply chain's environmental performance. From the perspective of the environment, the "right" remanufacturer is identified as the firm whose remanufacturing business leads to less impact on the environment, i.e., a fewer weighted production quantity qn + (qr.
PROPOSITION 7. From the perspective of the environment, if or > of, supplier-remanufaoturing is preferred regardless of the value of (; if or < of, supplier-remanufaoturing is preferred if ( is large enough, otherwise, manufacturer-remanufacturing is preferred.
It is worth noting that, if or > of, the profit seeking supplier does not
remanufacture used products. However, Proposition 7 reveals that supplier-remanufacturing is then preferred from the perspective of the environment.
The economic intuition has been discussed by Xiong et al. (2013). Even with ( = 0,
although remanufacturing cannibalizes the sales of the new product, the profit seeking
supplier will strategically lower the new component price, e.g., w^2 < w^, making
the manufacturer better off by producing more new products, so remanufacturing is
then detrimental to the environment. On the other hand, if or < of, in the model of
manufacturer-remanufacturing, fewer new products will be produced; however, all used products will be remanufactured. Therefore, manufacturer-remanufacturing leads to fewer new products but more remanufactured products compared with supplier-remanufacturing. Intuitively, the desirability of
manufacturer-remanufacturing and supplier-remanufacturing depends on the value of t.
5. Conclusions
In this paper, motivated by the pilot program of auto part remanufacturing in China, we analyze the performance of manufacturer-remanufacturing and supplier-remanufacturing, and examine their desirability from different stakeholder perspectives. Most of our modeling elements are widely used in the literature, but a main deviation lies in the unit remanufacturing cost is allowed to be higher than the unit manufacturing cost, which is motivated by the fact that not all manufacturers and suppliers have the infrastructure and expertise to remanufacture cost-efficiently.
Our analytical result confirms that both the manufacturer and the supplier are more likely to engage in remanufacturing as the decreasing of the unit remanufacturing cost. However, a less-intuitive finding is that the manufacturer (and only the manufacturer) may engage in remanufacturing even if remanufacturing a used component is costlier than manufacturing a new one. This finding implies that manufacturers could start up remanufacturing even if its technology is not sophisticated, which is consistent with our observation of the development of remanufacturing in many industries where high-profile manufacturers like Boeing, Caterpillar, General Electric, IBM, Kodak, Volkswagen and Xerox initiate a business model in which remanufacturing is an integral part.
We also find that if remanufacturing costs less, both the manufacturer and the supplier are more likely to engage in remanufacturing as a marginal increase in
consumer willingness-to-pay for the remanufactured product; in contrast, if remanufacturing costs more, the manufacturer may forgo remanufacturing due to a marginal increase in consumer willingness-to-pay for the remanufactured product. Furthermore, it is demonstrated that supplier-remanufacturing is a dominant strategy for both the manufacturer and the supplier if the remanufacturing cost is low enough.
These findings delineate a clear trajectory to guide the development of remanufacturing from a business perspective. At the early stage when the remanufacturing technology is unsophisticated, i.e., remanufacturing has a cost disadvantage, manufacturers should pioneer, and then the direction to promote remanufacturing is to invest in process innovation and lower the remanufacturing cost. As the remanufacturing technology becomes more sophisticated, i.e., remanufacturing enjoys a cost advantage, suppliers should be encouraged to engage in remanufacturing, and then tactics such as consumer education could be adopted to increase consumer willingness-to-pay for the remanufactured product and accelerate the development of remanufacturing.
This paper also examines the desirability of manufacturer-remanufacturing and supplier-remanufacturing from the perspective of the consumers and the environment, which may guide consumer groups and environmental organizations to lobby. As Xiong et al. (2013) commented, a simple governmental policy to spur more remanufacturing activities may be detrimental to both the industry and the environment. Given the tensions between different stakeholder perspectives, the government has to make a tradeoff and deliberate on the policy to take the full advantage of remanufacturing for a sustainable future.
Acknowledgements
Authors are listed alphabetically. The authors thank the editors and the review team for their valuable comments that have significantly improved the quality of this paper. Y. Xiong's work was supported by the National Natural Science Foundation of China (71301178) and Chongqing's Natural Science Foundation (cstc2012jjA1404), and Y.
Zhou's work was supported by the Foundation of China's Ministry of Education (14YJC630218) and the National Natural Science Foundation of China (71271225 and 71572021).
Appendixes
Proof of Proposition 1
In the model of manufacturer-remanufacturing, the Lagrangean and the KKT optimality conditions for the manufacturer's optimization problem are
L = (p„{qf , )-^^ ) qf + (pr(£ , )-C ) qf + Aqf -A (qf - qf ), (A1)
8L/8qf = 1 - 2qf - 2Sqf - w„ + A = 0, (A2)
dL/dqf = -S(qf + qf ) + S(l-qf -qf )-c,. + A -A = 0, (A3)
A qf = A (qf - qf ) = 0, (A4)
qf * qf * 0. (A5)
Because the multipliers A and A can be either zero or positive, we have four scenarios to examine.
Scenario 1 with A > 0 and A = 0 : we have qf = 0 according to the
optimality condition (A4); substituting A = 0 and qf = 0 back into equations
(A2) and (A3) gives qf = (1 - wn )/2 and A = cr -Swn ; here, A > 0 requires
wn <cr/S
Scenario 2 with A = 0 and A = 0 : by solving simultaneous equations (A2) and (A3), we have qf2 = (1 -wn-S + cr)/2(1 -à) and qf2 = (Swn -cr)/2S(1 -S) ; the optimality condition (A5) requires cr/S< w <(c + Scr +S-S2)/2S.
Scenario 3 with \= 0 and 0 : similar to Scenario 1, we have C = q3 =(1 - % + 8- cr )/2 (1 + 35) and X, =( 25w„ +52-5-cr -5cr )/(1 + 35), which requires wn >(cr + 8cr +8-8228.
Scenario 4 with \ > 0 and \ > 0 : according to the optimality condition (A4), we have qMA = = 0, which is trivial and discarded.
Proof of Proposition 2
Scenario M1. We assume that in this scenario the supplier behaves to let the manufacturer chooses \qMx, qM}. Thus, her optimization problem is
max nM =(wM -c„)qM, (A6)
subject to wM < cr /8, which guarantees that the manufacturer will respond by
choosing {q^, qM}, see Proposition 1. It is easy to get the unconstrained optimal
solution wMx = (1 + cn )/2, which is the optimal wholesale price if cr >8(1 + cn )/2
according to the constraint ^ < cr /8. If cr <8(1 + c )/2, then the optimal
wholesale price in this case is infinitely closed to cr /8, which is dominated by
w^ = cr /8 (we get this solution in the next case).
Scenario M2. In this scenario, we assume that the supplier behaves to let the manufacturer chooses {qM, }. The optimization problem is
n MM =W-cn)C, (A7)
subject to cr/8 < wM < (cr +8cr +8-8228. Similar to the proof of Proposition 1 we have the optimal wholesale price
(i) wL = cr/8, if c, >8(1 + c„ -8)/(2 - 8) ;
(ii) w^-2 = (1 + cn-S + Cr)/2, if Scn <Cr <S(1 + cn -S)/(2-S) ;
(iii) wL = (cr +SCr +S-S2)/2S, if cr <SCn.
Scenario M3. In this scenario, we assume that the supplier behaves to let the manufacturer chooses jqf, qf}. The optimization problem is
max nm = (wf - Cn ) qf3, (A8)
subject to wf > (c + Scr + S - S2 )/2S, and then similar to Case M1, the optimal
wholesale price is wf = (l + S + cn -cr)/2 if cr <S(cn + 2S)/(1 + 2S).
Next, we are to identify the optimal wholesale price on the whole parameter space. With S > 1/2, it is easy to prove that
S (cn + 2S)/(1 + 2S)>S (1 + cn )/2 >S (1 + cn-S)/(2-S)>Scn. Thus, if
cr >S(1 + cn)/2, the supplier has two possible solutions: (1) wM and letting the
manufacturer chooses \qf, qM}, and (2) and letting the manufacturer chooses
{q„i,qf } . Solving for nf «,g^,£) > nf (wl,qf2,qf ), we get
cr > S (1 + cn )/2. Thus, in this situation, the wholesale price wf is a dominant
strategy for the supplier. Similarly, it can be demonstrated that from the perspective of
the supplier, wM is preferred over wM if S (1 + cw )/2 < cr < S (cn + 2S)/(1 + 2S) ;
wf2-1 is preferred over wf3 if S(1 + cn-S)/(2-S)<cr <S(1 + cn)/2; wf3 is preferred over wf2_3 if cr < Scn.
If Scn < c <S(1 + c -S)/(2 -S), two possible solutions are: (1) wf2_2 and letting the manufacturer chooses {qf2, qf2}, and (2) wf and letting the manufacturer chooses {qf3,qf}. Let AM =nf (wM-2,qM2,qf )-nf 43,qM3), we have 8AM/8c,. >0, AM (cr =Scn) = -(S(1 -cn))2/2(1 + 3S)<0, and
AM (cr = 8(1 + c - 8)/(2 - 8)) = (2 - 38) 8(1 - c )2 ¡2 (1 + 38) (2 - 8)2. In this scenario, if 8 > 2/3, AM (cr =8(1 + - 8)/(2 - 8)) < 0, thus wM3 is always preferred over wM2_2; if 12 <8 < 2/3, AM (cr =8(1 + c„ - 8)/( 2 - 8)) > 0, and then there exists cM (its expression can be found in Proposition 2) such that WM is preferred if 8cn < cr < cM, otherwise, wM2_2 is preferred.
The Scenario with 8 < 1/2 is a simplification of that with 12 < 8 < 2/3. With 1/3<8< 12, we can skip the comparison of wM and wM, and with 8< 1/3, we can further skip the comparison of wM2_x and wM3. The results are all the same in
the Scenario with 12 < 8 < 2/3 .
Combining the above analysis and comparison gives the supplier's optimal wholesale price of the new component in the model of manufacturer-remanufacturing.
Proof of Proposition 3
Scenario S1. In this scenario, we assume that the supplier behaves to let the manufacturer chooses \qSnl, qSrl j. The optimization problem is
max nS1 = (wS - c ) q* + (wS - c) qS1, (A9)
subject to w^ < wS/8. It is easy to get that the unconstrained solution is w^ = (1 + c )/2, which is the optimal wholesale price of the new component if wfi > 8wSnl. Because n^ is independent in wl, we do not care about the exact value of wSn. As we will get in the next case, with {wf2_2, 2 j, we have q% = qfi = 0. Thus, the solutions, |wS, w^ j and \wSn2_x, j, are equivalent.
Scenario S2. In this scenario, we assume that the supplier behaves to let the manufacturer chooses \qSn2, qSr2 j. The optimization problem is
max nS2 = (wS -c)q* +(wS -c,)q*, (A10)
subject to wS/ô < wS < (wS + SwS +S-S2)/25. Similar to the proof of Proposition 1, we have the optimal wholesale prices of new and remanufactured components
(i) wS2-i = (1 + cn )/2, wS2-1 = ô (1 + c„ )/2, if c, > ôc„ ;
(ii) wS2-2 =(1 + c„)/2, wS2_2 =(ô + c,.)/2, if ô(2c„ +ô-1V(1 + ô)<c, <ôc„ ;
(iii) wL = (1 + 45 - ô2 + (1 + ô) (cn + c, ))/2 (1 + 35),
-3 = ô (2ô + c„ + c,. )/(1 + 3ô), if c,. < ô (2c„ + ô -1)/(1 + ô). Scenario S3. In this scenario, we assume that the supplier behaves to let the manufacturer chooses jq^, q% j. The optimization problem is
max n S 3 = ( wS - c ) q* + ( wS - c, ) q%, (A11)
wS ,wS
subject to wS > (wS + ôwS + ô - ô2 )/2ô. Because of q^ = q^, the optimization problem can be rewritten as
max nS3 = (w + w -c -cr)q^ . (A12)
wS , wj, x /
Clearly, n^ is concave in the sum of wS and wS . We have the unconstrained solutions satisfy wSn3 + w^ = (l + ô + cw + cr )/2. Without loss of generality, we set w^ = w^_3, the unconstrained relationship wSn3 + wSr3 = (l + ô + c + c )/2 requires w^ = , and the constraint
wSn > (wS + 8wS +S-S2)/28 requires wSn3 is infinitely closed to wS2_3. Thus, we
say that the solutions, {w^, w^} and {3, w^2_3}, are equivalent.
Combining the above analysis and comparison gives the supplier's optimal wholesale prices of new and remanufactured components in the model of supplier-remanufacturing.
Proof of Proposition 4
Clearly, we have six scenarios to compare the manufacturer's profits. We define AM! = nM -nM in scenario I.
In Scenario 1 with cr > cf, AM1 = 0 .
In Scenario 2 with cf < cr < cf, 92AM2/dcr2 = 1/282 > 0, letting 9AM2/9cr = 0, we have cr =8, that is to say, AM2 reaches its global minimum at c =8. In addition, the condition of this scenario implies cf < cf <8. Thus, we have Am 2 ^AM 2 (cr = cM ) = 0.
In Scenario 3 with cf < cr < cf, similar to Scenario 2, we have AM3 > 0. In Scenario 4 with cSx < cr < cf, 92AM4 /dcr2 = 1/8 (1 + 38) > 0, in addition, the condition of this scenario implies cS < cf < cf. We have Am 4 (c = cM ) = -8(l-8) (8 - 38) (1 - c )2(1 + 38) (2-8)2< 0,and Am4 (c = cS ) = - 8 (1 - 8) (1 - c )716 (1 + 38) < 0. Thus, Am4 < 0 .
In Scenario 5 with c\ < cr < c\, AM5 = -(8 + c + 8cr -28c -82)2/168(1 + 38)(1 - 8) < 0. In Scenario 6 with cr < cl, AM6 = 0.
Combining these results in all six scenarios gives Proposition 4.
Proof of Proposition 5
Similarly, we define A^ = nf -nSs in scenario I. In Scenario 1 with cr > cf, AS1 = 0 .
In Scenario 2 with cf < c < cf, A^2=-(8 + 8c„ -2cr)2/88< 0. In Scenario 3 with cf < c < cf, 92A^3 /dcr2 = 1/8 (1 - 8) > 0, letting 9A^3 /9^ = 0, we have cr = 8 + cw -1, that is to say, A^3 reaches its global minimum at cr = 8 + cw -1. In addition, the condition of this scenario implies 8 + c -1 < cf < cf. Thus, A3 is increasing in cr. We have
In Scenario 4 with csx < cr < cf, similar to Scenario 3, we have A54 < 0. In Scenario 5 with c\ < cr < c\,
In Scenario 6 with cr < , A^6 = 0.
Combining these results in all six scenarios gives Proposition 5. Proof of Proposition 6
Similarly, we define Ay/ = uM -uS in scenario l. In Scenario 1 with cr > cM, Ayl = 0.
In Scenario 2 with cf < c < cf, 92Ao2/9cr2 = 1/482 > 0, letting 9Au2/9cr = 0, we have cr = qM, that is to say, A^3 reaches its global minimum at cr = cM. We have A^ > A^ (cr = cM ) = 0.
A s 3 * A S3 ( c = cM ) = - (1 - c„ )2 S2/8 ( 2 -S)2 < 0.
In Scenario 3 with cM < c < cM, 52Au3/dcr2 = -(8 - 68)/328(1 -8) < 0, letting 5Au3 /5cr = 0, we have cr = (3 + C - 38) 8/(4 - 38), that is to say, Au3 reaches its global maximum at cr = (3 + cw - 38) 8/(4 - 38). In addition, the condition of this scenario implies cf < cM < cM < (3 + cn - 38) 8/(4 - 38). Thus, Au is increasing in cr. We have Au3>A^3(cr = cf ) = 38(1 -cn)2/32>0.
In Scenario 4 with cf < cr < cM, similar to Scenario 3, we have Au4 < 0. In Scenario 5 with cf < cr < cf, A.5 = -(8 + c + 8cr -28cw -82)2/328(1 + 38)(1 -8) < 0. In Scenario 6 with cr < cf, Au6 = 0 .
Combining these results in all six scenarios gives Proposition 6. Proof of Proposition 7
Similarly, we define AE/ = EM -Es in scenario l. In Scenario 1 with cr > cM, AE1 = 0.
In Scenario 2 with cM < cr < cM, AE2 = (8 + 8cw - 2cr V48, clearly, AE2 is decreasing in cr . Thus, we have AE2 >AE 2 (cr = cM ) = 0.
In Scenario 3 with cM < cr < cM, 5AE3 /5^ > 0. Thus, AE3 > A3 (^ = 0) = (C - 8cw V4 (1 - 8). In addition, the condition of this scenario implies cf < cM < cM. Thus, AE3 > A3 (cr = cf ) = 0.
In Scenario 4 with cf < cr < cM, Ae4 (¿ = 0, cr = cf ) = -8(1 - c„)/2 (1 + 38) < 0 and
AE4 (^ = 1, c = cf ) = (1 - 8) (1 - c V 4 (1 + 38) > 0. Thus, in this scenario, there must
exist a threshold value (letting ÀE4 = 0, we have)
< = < = ( 28 + cr - 38cn )/(1 - cw + 8-cr ) such that if <><, ÀE4 > 0; otherwise,
ÀE 4 < 0-
In Scenario 5 with cS < cr < cS, similar to Scenario 4, there exists a threshold value < = < = 28/(l + 8) such that if < > < , ÀE5 > 0 ; otherwise, ÀE5 < 0 . In Scenario 6 with cr < cS, = 0.
Combining these results in all six scenarios gives Proposition 7. References
Abbey, J. D., M. G. Meloy, V. D. R. Guide and S. Atalay. 2015. "Remanufactured Products in Closed-Loop Supply Chains for Consumer Goods." Production and Operations Management 24(3): 488-503. Atasu, A., V. D. R. Guide and L. N. Van Wassenhove. 2008. "Product Reuse Economics in Closed-Loop Supply Chain Research." Production and Operations Management 17(5): 483-496. Atasu, A., V. D. R. Guide and L. N. Van Wassenhove. 2010. "So What If Remanufacturing Cannibalizes My New Product Sales?" California Management Review 52(2): 56-76. Atasu, A., M. Sarvary and L. N. Van Wassenhove. 2008. "Remanufacturing as a
Marketing Strategy." Management Science 54(10): 1731-1746. Ayres, R., G. Ferrer and T. V. Leynseele. 1997. "Eco-efficiency, asset recovery and
remanufacturing." European Management Journal 15(5): 557-574. Caner, S., S. X. Zhu and R. Teunter. 2013. "Capacity and production decisions under a remanufacturing strategy." International Journal of Production Economics 145(1): 359-370.
Caterpillar. 2010. "The Remanufacturing Process." Available at
http://unitedkingdom.cat.com/cda/files/1414983/77reman_process.pdf (accessed date June 01, 2015).
Chang, X., H. Xia, H. Zhu, T. Fan and H. Zhao. 2015. "Production decisions in a hybrid manufacturing-remanufacturing system with carbon cap and trade mechanism." International Journal of Production Economics 162: 160-173.
Chen, J.-M. and C.-I. Chang. 2013. "Dynamic pricing for new and remanufactured products in a closed-loop supply chain." International Journal of Production Economics 146(1): 153-160.
Debo, L. G., L. B. Toktay and L. N. Van Wassenhove. 2005. "Market Segmentation and Product Technology Selection for Remanufacturable Products." Management Science 51(8): 1193-1205.
Ferguson, M. E. (2010). Strategic Issues in Closed-Loop Supply Chains with Remanufacturing. Closed-Loop Supply Chains: New Developments to Improve the Sustainability of Business Practices. M. E. Ferguson and G. C. Souza. Boca Raton, FL, Auerbach Publications.
Ferrer, G. and J. M. Swaminathan. 2006. "Managing New and Remanufactured Products." Management Science 52(1): 15-26.
Fleischmann, M., J. v. Nunen and B. Grave. 2003. "Integrating closed-loop supply chains and spare-parts management at IBM " Interfaces 33(6): 44-56.
Galbreth, M., T. Boyaci and V. Verter. 2013. "Product Reuse in Innovative
Industries." Production and Operations Management 22(4): 1011-1033.
Geyer, R., L. N. V. Wassenhove and A. Atasu. 2007. "The Economics of
Remanufacturing Under Limited Component Durability and Finite Product Life Cycles." Management Science 53(1): 88-100.
Gu, W., D. Chhajed, N. C. Petruzzi and B. Yalabik. 2015. "Quality design and environmental implications of green consumerism in remanufacturing." International Journal of Production Economics 162: 55-69.
Guide, V. D. R. and L. N. Van Wassenhove. 2009. "The Evolution of Closed-Loop Supply Chain Research." Operations Research 57(1): 10-18.
Guide, V. D. R. and L. N. V. Wassenhove. 2003. "Business Aspects of Closed-Loop Supply Chains." Carnegie-Bosch Institute, Pittsburgh.
Heese, H. S., K. Cattani, G. Ferrer, W. Gilland and A. V. Roth. 2005. "Competitive Advantage through Take-Back of Used Products." European Journal of Operational Research 164(1): 143-157.
Hong, X., L. Xu, P. Du and W. Wang. 2015. "Joint advertising, pricing and collection decisions in a closed-loop supply chain." International Journal of Production Economics 167: 12-22.
Huawei. 2015. "Huawei Green Recycling Program." Available at
http://consumer.huawei.com/en/support/recycling/ (accessed date September 01, 2015).
Liu, H., L. Liang, H. Zhang and W. Li. 2009. "Study on Consumers' Awareness and Purchase Behavior of Remanufactured Products in China." Operations Research and Management Science 18(4): 159-163.
Savaskan, R. C., S. Bhattacharya and L. N. Van Wassenhove. 2004. "Closed-Loop Supply Chain Models with Product Remanufacturing." Management Science 50(2): 239-252.
Sina. 2008. "List of pilot enterprises of auto part remanufacturing." Available at http://auto.sina.com.cn/news/2008-03-16/1624355214.shtml (accessed date June 01, 2015).
Souza, G. C. 2013. "Closed-Loop Supply Chains: A Critical Review, and Future Research." Decision Sciences 44(1): 7-38.
Wei, S., O. Tang and W. Liu. 2015. "Refund policies for cores with quality variation in OEM remanufacturing." International Journal of Production Economics 170(Part B): 629-640.
Wu, C.-H. 2015. "Strategic and operational decisions under sales competition and collection competition for end-of-use products in remanufacturing." International Journal of Production Economics 169: 11-20.
Xiong, Y., G. Li, Y. Zhou, K. Fernandes, R. Harrison and Z. Xiong. 2014. "Dynamic pricing models for used products in remanufacturing with lost-sales." International Journal of Production Economics 147(Part C): 678-688.
Xiong, Y., Y. Zhou, G. Li, H.-K. Chan and Z. Xiong. 2013. "Don't Forget Your
Supplier When Remanufacturing." European Journal of Operational Research 230(1): 15-25.
Zhou, Y., Y. Xiong, G. Li, Z. Xiong and M. Beck. 2013. "The Bright Side of
Manufacturing-Remanufacturing Conflict in a Decentralised Closed-Loop Supply Chain." International Journal of Production Research 51(9): 2639-2651.
Highlights
• We analyze and compare manufacturer-remanufacturing and supplier-remanufacturing.
• The manufacturer may engage in remanufacturing even if it is costlier than manufacturing.
• A marginal increase in willingness-to-pay for the remanufactured product may deter remanufacturing.
• The manufacturer may prefer supplier-remanufacturing.
• The supplier never prefers manufacturer-remanufacturing.