J Ind Eng Int
DOI 10.1007/s40092-015-0135-5
ORIGINAL RESEARCH
Jjjjj^ CrossMark
Pricing in a two-echelon supply chain with different market powers: game theory approaches
Afshin Esmaeilzadeh1 • Ata Allah Taleizadeh1
Received: 7 April 2015/Accepted: 5 December 2015
© The Author(s) 2015. This article is published with open access at Springerlink.com
Abstract In this research, the optimal pricing decisions for two complementary products in a two-echelon supply chain under two scenarios are studied. The proposed supply chain in each echelon includes one retailer and two manufacturers and the same complementary products are produced. In the first scenario, we assume the unit manufacturing costs of the complementary products in each echelon are the same, while in the second one the different unit manufacturing costs are supposed and lead to demand leakage from the echelon with the higher unit manufacturing cost to the echelon with the lower unit manufacturing cost. Moreover, under the second scenario, the products with lower price are replaced with the higher price products. The purpose of this study is to analyze the effects of different market powers between the manufacturers and the retailer and the demand leakage on the optimal wholesale and retail prices and also on the profit of the chain. The relationships between the manufacturers and the retailer are modeled by the MS-Stackelberg and MS-Bertrand game-theoretic approach where the manufacturers are leaders and the retailers are followers.
Keywords Pricing • Complementary products • Market power • MS-Stackelberg game • MS-Bertrand game
Introduction and literature review
Market power as the principal companies' success factors is a primitive and important challenge to which companies are faced. The companies, which are competing in the same
& Ata Allah Taleizadeh Taleizadeh@ut.ac.ir
1 School of Industrial Engineering, College of Engineering, University of Tehran, Tehran, Iran
market, are attempting to increase own market penetrations by using different implements to achieve the more market power than the other rivals. The market power leads to enhance the penetrability of companies so that the market would be handled by the powerful firms (Wei et al. 2013; Zhao et al. 2014). One of the practical and the efficient implements which cause to improve the companies' revenue and also their power market is presenting an optimal price where the same products are launched to the market. So, pricing policy as the useful tool which can solve this imperative problem is recognized by enterprises for decades. In fact, the companies attempt to optimize their selling prices to acquire the more market demand.
Recently, many researchers are focused on the pricing policies. For instance, Starr and Rubinson (1978) proposed a model to survey the relation between the demand of product and its prices. Dada and Srikanth (1987) studied pricing policies under quantity discounts. Kim and lee (1998) employed pricing and ordering strategies for a single item with fixed or variable capacity to maximize the profit of firm faced to price-sensitive and deterministic demand over a planning horizon. Boyaci and Gallego (2002) considered joint pricing and ordering decisions in a supply chain consisting of a wholesaler and one or several retailers. A complete review of dynamic pricing models was presented by Elmaghraby and Keskinocak (2003). Several studies applied pricing policy with coordination mechanisms under different assumptions (Chen and Sim-chi-Levi 2004a, b, 2006; Chen et al. (2006); Xiao et al. (2010); Wei and Zhao (2011); Yu and Ma (2013); Maihami and Karimi (2014); Taleizadeh and Noori-daryan (2014)). Sinha and Sarmah (2010) studied pricing decisions in a distribution channel under the competition and coordination issues in which two competitive vendors sell products to a common retailer in the same market. A comprehensive
Published online: 26 December 2015
a Springer
review of pricing models for a multi-product system is performed by Soon (2011). Shavandi et al. (2012) presented a new constrained pricing and inventory model for perishable products which those are classified to complementary, substitutable and independent products. Their aim is to optimize the prices, inventory and production decisions such that the total profit is maximized. Mahmoodi and Eshghi (2014) presented three algorithms to obtain the optimal pricing decisions in a duopoly supply chain. Taleizadeh et al. (2014) developed a vendor managed inventory (VMI) model in a two-level supply chain including a vendor and multiple retailers to survey the optimal pricing and inventory policies such that the total profit of the chain is maximized.
The concept of complementary products is suggested when the customer has to purchase more than one product at the same time so that the products could have the required efficiency (Yue et al. 2006). For an instance, software and hardware systems of a computer are two complementary products and should be purchased together to have the required efficiency for the customer. But, if a customer is not satisfied enough with a purchased product and purchases a similar product, then these two products will be substitutable products. For example; different marks of software or hardware systems of a computer may be considered as substitutable products. Several researchers examine the effects of complementary and substi-tutable products on the profit of inventory systems. For example, the pricing decisions of two complementary products as the bundle policy is studied by Yue et al. (2006) where the products are produced by two separate firms. Mukhopadhyay et al. (2011) considered a duopoly market where two independent firms offer complementary goods under information asymmetry. The Stackelberg game-theoretic model to solve the proposed model is utilized. Yan and Bandyopadhyay (2011) proposed a profit-maximization model and applied a bundle pricing policy for complementary items. Wei et al. (2013) examined the pricing problem under the different market powers structures between members of a supply chain with two manufacturers and one retailer for two complementary products. Wang et al. (2014) employed pricing policy for two complementary products in a fuzzy environment and they survey the changes of the optimal retail prices of two complementary products under two different scenarios. Wei et al. (2015) presented joint optimal pricing and warranty period of two complementary products in a supply chain with two manufacturers and one common retailer under horizontal firm's cooperation/noncooperation strategies.
Tang and Yin (2007) extended the Starr and Rubinson (1978)'s work for two substitutable products under the fixed and variable pricing strategies. The goal of this paper
is to jointly determine optimal order quantity and retail price. Hsieh and Wu (2009) and Gurler and Yilmaz (2010) employed coordinating mechanisms for substitutable products under various assumptions. Then two problems are carried out by Zhao et al. (2012a, b) such that in the first one, a pricing problem of substitutable products in a fuzzy environment is discussed. In the second one, a pricing policy in a supply chain including one manufacturer and two competitive retailers for substitutable products where the customers' demand and the manufacturing costs are non-deterministic is employed. Chen et al. (2013) discussed pricing problem for substitutable products under traditional and online channels in a two-stage supply chain including a manufacturer and a retailer where the manufacturer sells a product to a retailer and also sells directly to customers through an online channel. Hsieh et al. (2014) surveyed pricing and ordering decisions of partners of a supply chain including multiple manufacturers and a retailer under demand uncertainty where each manufacturer produces a different substitutable product which is sold through the retailer. Zhao et al. (2014) developed a pricing model for substitutable products under the different market power of firms in a supply chain with two competitive manufacturers and a retailer. Fei et al. (2015) considered a price model for one supplier and multiple retailers under different product substitution degrees. In this article, the authors studied the effect of sub-packaging cost on the retail price.
Panda et al. (2015) studied joint pricing and replenishment policies in a dual-channel supply chain where the manufacturer is the leader of Stackelberg model. Zhang et al. (2014) developed a dynamic pricing model in a competitive supply chain under deterministic demand function to optimize the benefits of supply chain members. Also, they analyzed the profit sensitivity with respect to various factors. Giri and Sharma (2014) developed pricing model under cooperative and non-cooperative advertising in a supply chain with a single manufacturer and two competitive retailers. Consumer demand function depends on price and advertising. They show that cooperative advertising policy is more beneficial.
After reviewing comprehensively pricing problems of complementary and substitutable products, we found although several pricing models are developed to optimize the profit or cost of the inventory systems for complementary and substitutable products, the pricing problem of both complementary and substitutable products in a two-echelon supply chain with market power and demand leakage considerations is not discussed.
In this paper, a pricing model of complementary and substitutable products in a two-echelon supply chain in which each echelon including two manufacturers and one retailer under demand leakage is developed, where the
different market powers are assumed for the chain members. Two different game-theoretic approaches including MS-Stackelberg and MS-Bertrand are employed to examine the pricing decisions of the chain members when the market power is different and subsequently demand leaks from one echelon to the second one.
The rest of the paper is organized as follows. The problem is described in Sect. 2. The model is formulated in Sect. 3. Section 4 provides solution methods under MS-Stackelberg and MS-Bertrand game-theoretic approaches. Sections 5 and 6 contain a numerical example, sensitivity analysis and conclusion as a summary of findings and some future researches.
Problem description
Consider a two-echelon supply chain including one retailer and two manufacturers in every echelon where each echelon supplies two complementary products. In the first echelon, manufacturers 1 and 2, respectively, produce two complementary products 1 and 2 and wholesale the products to retailer 1. Then retailer 1 sells the products 1 and 2 to the customers. In the second one, manufacturers 3 and 4 produce two complementary products 3 and 4 and wholesale them to retailer 2. Therefore, retailer 2 sells the products 3 and 4 to the customers. We assume two complementary products produced in each echelon of supply chain are the same such that products 1 and 3 and products 2 and 4 are the same.
In other words, based on Fig. 1 in which the schema of the supply chain is shown, the manufacturer i produces product i at unit manufacturing cost Ci and sells it to retailer j at unit wholesale price Wi. Afterward, the retailer j sells the product i to end users at unit retail price Pi where in the first echelon i = 1, 2j = 1 and in the second echelon i = 3,4j = 2. Moreover, we assume that if the unit manufacturing cost Ci is different in each echelon of supply chain, the demand leakage from the echelon with the higher unit manufacturing cost to the
echelon with lower unit manufacturing cost occurs. Therefore, the products 1 and 3 and also the products 2 and 4 will be transacted in the market as the substi-tutable products. This scheme can be used for software and hardware systems of a computer as described in previous section. These products are complementary and are produced by manufacturers 3 and 4, as different brands, respectively. So, if a customer is not satisfied enough from the purchased products of manufacturer 1 and 2, then products 1 and 3 and products 2 and 4 will be substitutable products.
The assumptions utilized to model the discussed problem are as follows.
1. Demand is deterministic and price-sensitive.
2. The same complementary products are produced in each echelon.
3. In the first model, the same unit manufacturing costs are considered for each echelon.
4. In the second model, different unit manufacturing costs are assumed for each echelon which is caused demand leakage between two echelons of the chain. So, the product with the higher unit manufacturing cost will be substituted by the products with the lower unit manufacturing cost.
5. The higher market power is assumed for the manufacturers than the retailer in each echelon so that the market is managed by the manufacturers.
6. Shortage is not allowed.
7. All the parameters are deterministic and positive.
The main aim of this paper is to study the optimal pricing policies in a two-echelon supply chain for two complementary products under two scenarios with the different market powers of each echelon partners. Two manufacturers and one retailer are the partners of each echelon and the problem is to determine the optimal values of wholesale prices of the manufacturers and the selling prices of the retailers to maximize the profit of the chain.
The following notations are used to develop the problem.
Fig. 1 A two-echelon supply chain
Parameters
C,- The unit manufacturing cost of product i;
A; The primary demand of customers for product i; b,-,- The self-price sensitivity for the demand of ith
product respect to its own price; b,j The cross price sensitivities for the demand of ith
product respect to the price of jth product j, bn > bij L1 The factor of demand leakage between products 1 and 3;
L2 The factor of demand leakage between products 2 and 4;
D,- The demand rate of customers for product i under the first scenario;
Di The demand rate of customers for product i under the
second scenario; pmi The profit function of manufacturer i under the first scenario;
pm The profit function of manufacturer i under the
second scenario; prj The profit function of retailer j under the first scenario;
pjj The profit function of retailer j under the second scenario;
Decision variables
W The wholesale price of product i per unit, ($); Pj The retail price of product i per unit, ($)
The optimal values of the decision variables of the models under the both scenarios are shown by sign (*). In addition, some notations utilized to model the first and the second models are defined in Appendices 1 and 2, respectively.
Mathematical model
In this section, two pricing models for the complementary products with and without demand leakage considerations in a two-echelon supply chain are developed where two manufacturers and one retailer are the partners of each echelon.
The first model: without demand leakage
In this model, the same unit manufacturing costs are considered for the manufacturers of each echelon. So, the demand leakage between two echelons is not occurred. Thus, the demand functions of complementary products 1, 2, 3, and 4 are formulated as follows.
D1 = A1 - b11P1 - b12P2 (1)
D2 = A2 - b22P2 - b21P1 (2)
D3 = A3 - b33P3 - b34P4 D4 = A4 - b44P4 - b43P3
And the profit functions of the manufacturers and the retailers are represented as follows.
Pm1 (W1) = (W1 - C1)[A1 - bnP1 - b12P2] (5)
Pm2(W2) = (W2 - C2) [A2 - b22P2 - b21P1] (6)
Pr1(P1, P2) = (P1 - W1)[A1 - bnP1 - A2P2]
+ (P2 - W2) [A2 - b22P2 - b21P1 ] (7)
Pm3(W3) = (W3 - C3)[A3 - b33P3 - b34P4] (8)
Pm4(W4) = (W4 - C4) [A4 - b44P4 - b43P3] (9)
Pr2(P3; P4) = (P3 - W3)[A3 - b33P3 - b34P4]
+ (P4 - W4) [A4 - b44P4 - b43P3] (10)
The second model with demand leakage
In this case, a symmetrical demand leakage between two echelons of supply chain due to the different unit manufacturing costs of two echelons is considered. The demand leakage occurs between products 1 and 3 and also between products 2 and 4. As a result, products 1 and 3 and products 2 and 4 can be traded as the substitutable products. So, the demand functions of products 1, 2, 3, and 4 are obtained as follows:
D1 = A1 - b1P1 - L1(P1 - P3)
D2 = A2 - b2P2 - ¿2(P2 - P4) D3 = A3 - b3P3 + L1(P1 - P3) D4 = A4 - b4P4 + L2(P2 - P4)
(11) (12)
Meanwhile, the following relationships are established between bii,bij, and Li
bii = bi + Li bj = Li
Hence, the profit functions of the manufacturers and retailers are represented as follows:
PUW1) = (W1 - C1)[A1 - b1P1 - L1 (P1 - P3)]
P^2(W2) = (W2 - C2) [A2 - b2P2 - L2(P2 - P4)]
p;1(P1, P2) = (P1 - W1)[A1 - b1P1 - L1 (P1 - P3)] + (P2 - W2)[A2 - b2P2 - L2(P2 - P4)]
P^3(W3) = (W3 - C3)[A3 - b3P3 + L1 (P1 - P3)] (20) PUW4) = (W4 - C4) [A4 - b4P4 + L2 (P2 - P4)] (21)
<2(Ps, P4) = (P3 - Ws)[A3 - bsPs + L (Pj - P3)]
+ (P4 - W4) [A4 - ¡iAP4 + L2(P2 - P4)]
Solution method
For solving the on hand problem, the MS game-theoretic approach is applied, in which the followers first make decision about their decision variables and then the leaders determine the optimal values of own decision variables according to the best reaction of the followers. Here, we consider the manufacturers as the Stackelberg leaders and the retailers as Stackelberg followers where the wholesale prices of the manufacturers and the retail prices of the retailers are the decision variables of the introduced model. So, the manufacturers have more market powers than the retailers and also the market is leaded by the manufacturers. Meanwhile, the theory of MS game consists of two practical approaches which are known as the MS-Bertrand and the MS-Stackelberg models. In this section, we intend to obtain the optimal values of the decision variables by employing the MS-Bertrand and the MS-Stackelberg models under both scenarios.
The MS-Bertrand model
Based on the MS-Bertrand approach, although the manufacturers as the leader have more market power than the retailers as the followers, in each echelon of supply chain the manufacturers have the same power and they move, simultaneously. The solution algorithm of MS-Bertrand model is presented in Fig. 2.
The first model under the MS-Bertrand approach
According to the MS-Bertrand solution algorithm, the optimal values of selling prices of four products versus the wholesale prices are obtained as follows:
Pi (W1, W2) = F1 + F2W1 + F3 W2 (23)
F5 W1 + F6 W2 (24)
-U2 W3 + U3 W4 (25)
-U5 W3 + U6 W4 (26)
P2(Wi, W2 ) = F4 P3(W3, W4 ) = Ui -P4(W3; W4 ) = U4 -
Substituting Eqs. (23)-(26) into the manufacturer's profit function, the optimal values of wholesale prices of products are acquired as follows:
E1E6 — E2E3
E4E6 - E5E3 E2E4 - E1E5 E4E6 - E5E3
a®, (p, ,pt )/sp, = 0
P,(w„Wl)
djfr (p, ,p) )/ap; = 0
(f, fr, ,w, ),p, (if, fr, = 0
p'ifr'.wj)
Fig. 2 The MS-Bertrand algorithm
G1G6 - G2G3
G4G6 - G5G3 G2G4 - G1G5 G4G6 - G5G3
Then, by substituting Eqs. (27)-(30) into Eqs. (23)-(26), the independent optimal selling prices can be obtained as:
P = Fi + F2
/EjE6 - E2E3
E4E6 - E5E3
/E1E6 - E2E3 \E4E6 - E5E3
p* = F4 + fJ EiE6 - E2EA + f/ E2E4 - EiE5)
V E4E6 - E5E3J \E4E6 - E5E3y
P3 = U1 + U2(G|G6 - GjGM + U3 f-3 1 ^ 2VG4G6 - G5G3J ^ 3V
G2G4 - G1G5
G4G6 - G5G3
4 4 5 G4G6 - G5G3) 6 (G4G6 - G5G3)
The second model under the MS-Bertrand approach
According to the MS-Bertrand solution algorithm, the optimal retail prices of four products versus the wholesale prices of the manufacturers are obtained as follows:
P\ (W1, W3) = K1 + K2W3 + K3W1 (35)
P2 ( W2, W4 ) = K4 + K5 W4 + K6 W2 (36)
p;(W1 ; W3 ) = K7 + K8W1 + K3W3 (37)
P*4(W2, W4) = K9 + K10W2 + K6W4 (38)
Substituting Eqs. (35)-(38) into the profit functions of manufacturers, the optimal values of wholesale prices are acquired as follows:
N1N6 - N2N3 " N4N6 - N5N3
n7n12 - n8n9
N10N12 - N11N9 N2N4 - N1N5 " N4N6 - N5N5 N8N10 - N7N11 N10N12 - N11N9
Therefore, by substituting Eqs. (39)-(42) into Eqs. (35)-(38), the optimal retail prices can be obtained independently as:
P* = K1 + K2(N2N4 - + kJN1N6 -N2N3^\
1 1 ^ N4N6 - N5N3J aN4N6 - n5n3 )
K4 + K( N8N10 - N7N11N
AN10N12 - N11N9; /N7N12 - N8N9 \ VN10N12 - N11N9;
K7 + fN1N6 - N2N3)
7 \N4N6 - N5N3J
/N2N4 -" - N5N3;
4 = K9
K /N7N12 - N8N9 \
10 VN10N12 - N11N9; /N8N10 - N7N11 \
U10N12 - N11N9J
The MS-Stackelberg model
Under this approach, the manufacturers, because of the more market powers, are considered as the leaders of Stackelberg and the retailers are considered as the followers. Moreover, in each echelon of supply chain, the manufacturers don't have the similar powers and they sequentially make decisions about own decision variables. Also the Stackelberg game is current between them such that one of the manufacturers plays the role of the Stackelberg leader and the other one is the follower of Stackelberg. The figurative MS-Stackelberg solution algorithm is indicated in Fig. 3 in which manufacturer i is the leader and manufacturer j is the follower.
The first model under the MS-Stackelberg approach
Based on the MS-Stackelberg algorithm, the optimal values of selling prices of four products versus the wholesale prices of manufacturers are obtained, similar to the MS-Bertrand model, as follows:
PÎ(W1, W2 ) = F1 -P2(W1; W2 ) = F4-P3(W3; W4 ) = U1-P4(W3; W4 ) = U4 -
F2W1 + F3 W2 F5W1 + F6 W2
- U2W3 + U3 W4
- U5W3 + U6W4
Since in the first echelon manufacturer 1 is the leader and manufacturer 2 is the follower, so by substituting Eqs. (47) and (48) into the profit functions of manufacturer 1 and 2, the optimal wholesale price of the manufacturer 1 is obtained as:
E2 e5 W2 = TT —W1 E6 E6
Then by substituting Eq. (52) into Eq. (51), the optimal wholesale price of manufacturer 2 is obtained as follows:
W2*= E2 - ^f E7 2 E6 E6 E8
In the second echelon of supply chain, manufacturer 3 is the leader and manufacturer 4 is the follower. Afterward, by substituting Eqs. (49) and (50) into the profit functions of the second echelon manufacturers, the optimal wholesale price of manufacturers 3 is obtained, so we have:
W4 = G6
Hence, the optimal value of manufacturer 4 is derived by substituting Eq. (55) into Eq. (54) as follows:
dn, (P, ,Pj )/dP, = 0
a/tr(p„pj)/№j=0
P.iW.Wj)
Pjiw.W,)
K ,p< K >wj )>pj K >wJ ))/8wJ -°
WjtW,)
Fig. 3 The MS-Stackelberg algorithm
W* = Gl-GL( G
Ge G^ \ G8
Therefore, by substituting Eqs. (52)-(56) into Eqs. (47)-(50), the independent retailers' optimal retail prices are obtained which are:
=+4Ю+ 4t - КI
= F4 + «(*) + *(f-16 g
P3 = u,++v3\G2 - G5 CG
P3 = U4 + U^ + US G G
G8 G6 G6 G8
G6 G6 G8 G2 G5 / G7
The second model wnder MS-Stackelberg approach
Based on the MS-Stackelberg algorithm, the optimal selling prices of four products versus the wholesale prices, which are obtained as the MS-Bertrand model, are as follows.
P(W, W3) = K + K2W3 + K3Wi (61)
P2(W2, W4 ) = K4 + K5W4 + K6W2 P3(Wi; W3) = K7 + K8Wi + K3W3 PÎ(W2, W4 ) = K9 + Kl0 W2 + K6W4
According to the assumptions, a symmetrical demand leakage occurs between two echelons of supply chain on the same products because of different unit manufacturing costs in the echelons. The demand leakage occurs between products 1 and 3 and also products 2 and 4. Here, we assume that the unit manufacturing costs of manufacturers 1 and 2 are larger than manufacturers 3 and 4. So, the manufacturers 1 and 2 lost their demand and the manufacturers 3 and 4 against earn more demands due to their lower unit manufacturing costs.
Therefore, manufacturers 3 and 4 handle the market owing to having the more powers than the other ones. As a result, manufacturers 3 and 4 are the Stackelberg leaders and manufacturers 1 and 2 are the Stackelberg followers. Thus, by substituting Eqs. (61) and (63) into the profit functions of manufacturers, the optimal wholesale price of manufacturer 1 is derived as follows:
w = N4- N4 w
Then, the optimal value of unit wholesale price of manufacturer lis obtained by substituting Eq. (66) into Eq. (65) which is:
w з= Ni_ Nif Nu
1 N4 N4I N14
Furthermore, by substituting Eqs. (62) and (64) into the objective functions of manufacturers 2 and 4, the optimal unit wholesale price of manufacturer 4 is:
W2 = 77^ — Tj W4 N10 N10
In addition, the optimal unit wholesale price of manufacturer 2 is obtained by substituting Eq. (69) into Eq. (68) which is:
n7 n9 /n15
N10 N10 VN16
Eventually, by substituting Eqs. (66)-(70) into Eqs. (61)-(64), the retailers' optimal unit retail prices can be obtained independently, as follows:
fN1 N3 /N13^
p = к, + K2
N4 N4 VN14
P2 = K4
- *5©+<—(72)
N, N3 /N13
K7 + KJ-4 TT3 l T74") + K3 т^ (73)
N4 N4 N14
n7 n9 / n15
4 = K9
N10 N10 VN16
K9 + K,0 —-M-^ + KJ-^ (74)
Numerical example and sensitivity analysis
In this section, a numerical example for a two-echelon supply chain including two manufacturers and one retailer in each echelon is presented. According to the assumption, the model is developed for two complementary products and price-sensitive demand. In addition, the discussed problem is formulated under two different scenarios where the MS-Stackelberg and the MS-Bertrand solution algorithms are employed to solve them. In this example, we consider A, = A2 = 180, A3 = A4 = 220, C, = C2 = 25, C3 = C4 = 20, bii = b33 = 0.5, b22 = b44 = 0.6, bl2 = b21 = 0.3, b34 = b43 = 0.35, bi3 = b31 = 0.3,
b24 = b42 = 0.35 and the results are shown in Tables 1 and 2.24 42
The findings obtained from Table 1 are summarized as follows.
• According to the obtained results of the first model, retailers 1 and 2 achieve their highest optimal retail prices for products 1 and 3 under the MS-Stackelberg
approach and also for products 2 and 4 under the MS-Bertrand approach.
• The highest optimal wholesale prices of products 1 and 3 are acquired under the MS-Stackelberg approach and also for products 2 and 4 under the MS-Bertrand approach in the first model. About the second model, the highest optimal wholesale prices and optimal retail prices of products 1, 2, 3, and 4 are achieved under the MS-Stackelberg approach.
From Table 2, the following results can be obtained too.
• In the first model, manufacturers 1 and 3 achieve their highest profits under the MS-Stackelberg approach and the manufacturers 2 and 4 achieve their highest profits under the MS-Bertrand approach. In the second model, all the manufacturers achieve their highest profits under the MS-Stackelberg approach.
• The retailers 1 and 2 achieve their highest profits using MS-Bertrand game-theoretic approach in the first model, and in the second model retailer 1 achieves his highest profit applying MS-Stackelberg game and retailer 2 achieves his highest profit using MS-Bertrand game.
• The whole supply chain achieves the maximum profit under the MS-Bertrand game-theoretic approach in the first and the second models.
To study the effect of changing the parameter values on the optimal values of the decision variables for this paper, a sensitivity analysis is performed. The sensitivity analysis for the first model is done only at the first echelon of supply chain and for the second model is done only between products 1 and 3. Tables 3, 4, 5 and 6 show the results of the first model under MS-Bertrand and MS-Stackelberg policies, respectively.
The findings obtained from Tables 3 and 4 are summarized as follows.
• Wj, Wj, Pj, P2, D1, D2, pm1, pm2 and pr1 are consumedly sensitive respect to the changes in parameters A1 and A2. When A1 and A2 are decreased by 25 and 50 %, all of decision variables decrease and vice versa.
• Wj, Wj, P\, P2, pm1 and pm2 are consumedly sensitive respect to the changes in parameters b11 and b22, while D1, D2 and pr1 are moderately sensitive respect to the
changes in value of b11 and b22. When b11 and b22 are decreased by 25 and 50 %, D1 and D2 decrease, while Wj, Wj, Pj, P2, pmi, pm2 and pr1 increase and vice versa.
• Wj, Wj, Pj, P2, D1, D2, pm1, pm2 and pr1 are moderately sensitive respect to the changes in b12 and b21. When bi2 and b21 are decreased by 25 and 50 %, all of the decision variables increase and vice versa.
• Wj, Wj, Pj and P2 are slightly sensitive respect to the changes in parameters C1 and C2, while D1, D2, pm1, pm2 and pr1 are moderately sensitive respect to the changes in value of C1 and C2. When C1 and C2 are decreased by 25 and 50 %, Wj, Wj, Pj and P*2 decrease while D1, D2, pmi, pm2 and pr1 increase and vice versa.
The results of Tables 5 and 6 are similar to the results of Tables 3 and 4, except for sensitivity analysis of b11 and b22. We assume manufacture 1 is the leader and manufacturer 2 is the follower. The results show Wj, Pj and pm1 are consumedly sensitive respect to the changes in parameters b11 and b22, while Wj, P*2 and pm2 are slightly sensitive respect to the changes in value of b11 and b22. When b11 and b22 are decreased by 25 and 50 %, Wj, P\ and pm1 increase while Wj, Pj and pm2 decrease. Also, sensitivity analysis is performed on the second model under MS-Bertrand policy and its results are shown Tables 7 and 8. Moreover the results of sensitivity analysis of the second model under MS-Stackelberg are shown in Tables 9 and 10.
The findings obtained from Tables 7 and 8 are summarized as follows.
• Wj, Wj, Pj, P3, D'j, D3, Pm1, pm3, рГ1 and рГ2 are moderately sensitive respect to the changes in parameters A1 and A3. When A1 and A3 are decreased by 25 and 50 %, all of decision variables decrease and vice versa.
• Wj, Wj, Pj, P3, D\, D3, Pm1, pm3, <1 and n'r2 are consumedly sensitive respect to the changes in parameters b1 and b3. When b1 and b3 are decreased by 25 and 50 %, all of the decision variables increase and vice versa.
• Wj, Wj, Pj, P3, D and D3 are moderately sensitive respect to the changes in parameters b13 and b31, while Pm1, n'm3, Pr1 and n'r2 are slightly sensitive respect to the changes in parameters b13 and b31. When b13 and b31
Table 1 Optimal decision of retail prices and wholesale prices under different decision scenarios
Decision scenario Model pi P2 P3 P4 Wj Wj Wj W4j
MS-Bertrand model 1 186.54 186.54 190.63 190.63 148.08 148.08 149.68 149.68
2 552.21 449.91 593.26 484.26 388.45 317.33 415.2 339.41
MS-Stackelberg model 1 193.29 184.51 197.27 188.69 161.59 144.02 162.97 145.8
2 555.97 452.59 601.48 490.3 391.04 319.18 429.38 349.92
Table 2 Maximum profits of the total system and for every firm under different decision scenarios
Decision scenario Model pm1 pm2 pm3 pm4 pr1 pr2 Total profit
MS-Bertrand model 1 3786.98 3786.98 5044.87 5044.87 2366.86 3186.23 23,216.79
2 29,758.21 23,253.79 35,148.92 27,760.29 23,953.38 28,442.13 1,68,352.72
MS-Stackelberg model 1 3824.39 3541.7 5088.86 47,47,071 2092.56 2839.66 22,134.88
2 30,184.27 23,548.64 35,227.14 27,788.51 24,279.06 26,633.38 1,67,661
Table 3 The sensitivity analysis for the first model in first echelon of supply chain under MS-Bertrand policy
Parameters % Changes Optimal values % Changes in
WT W2 p1 P2 D1 D2 WT W2 p1 P2 D1 D2
A1 ^ = A2 -50 78.85 78.85 95.67 95.67 13.46 13.46 -46.75 -46.75 -48.71 -48.71 -56.25 -56.25
-25 113.46 113.46 141.11 141.11 22.12 22.12 -23.38 -23.38 -24.36 -24.36 -28.13 -28.13
+25 182.69 182.69 231.97 231.97 39.42 39.42 23.38 23.38 24.36 24.36 28.13 28.13
+50 217.31 217.31 277.40 277.40 48.08 48.08 46.75 46.75 48.71 48.71 56.25 56.25
b11 = b22 -50 232.81 232.81 280.04 280.04 25.98 25.98 57.22 57.22 50.13 50.13 -15.58 -15.58
-25 180.36 180.36 223.51 223.51 29.13 29.13 21.80 21.80 19.82 19.82 -5.33 -5.33
+25 126.21 126.21 160.40 160.40 31.63 31.63 -14.77 -14.77 -14.01 -14.01 2.79 2.79
+50 110.42 110.42 140.92 140.92 32.03 32.03 -25.43 -25.43 -24.45 -24.45 4.10 4.10
b12 = b21 -50 167.39 167.39 222.16 222.16 35.60 35.60 13.04 13.04 19.09 19.09 15.69 15.69
-25 157.14 157.14 202.71 202.71 33.04 33.04 6.12 6.12 8.67 8.67 7.37 7.37
+25 140.00 140.00 172.86 172.86 28.75 28.75 -5.45 -5.45 -7.33 -7.33 -6.56 -6.56
+50 132.76 132.76 161.12 161.12 26.94 26.94 -10.34 -10.34 -13.63 -13.63 -12.45 -12.45
C1 ^ = C2 -50 143.27 143.27 184.13 184.13 32.69 32.69 -3.25 -3.25 -1.29 -1.29 6.25 6.25
-25 145.67 145.67 185.34 185.34 31.73 31.73 -1.62 -1.62 -0.64 -0.64 3.13 3.13
+25 150.48 150.48 187.74 187.74 29.81 29.81 1.62 1.62 0.64 0.64 -3.12 -3.12
+50 152.88 152.88 188.94 188.94 28.85 28.85 3.25 3.25 1.29 1.29 -6.25 -6.25
are decreased by 25 and 50 %, Wf, Wf, P\ and P3 increase, while D\, D'3, Pm1, Pm3, Pr1 and Pr2 decrease and vice versa.
• Wf, Wf, Pf, P3, D\, D3, Pm1, <3, <1 and <2 are slightly sensitive respect to the changes in value of Ci. When C1 is decreased by 25 and 50 %, Wf, W3f, P1, P|, D3, Pm3 and p'2 decrease, while D1, Pm1 and Pr1 increase and vice versa.
• Wf, Wf, Pf, P3, D1, D3, Pm1, Pm3, <1 and Pr2 are slightly sensitive respect to the changes in value of C3. When C3 is decreased by 25 and 50 %, Wf, W3f, P1, P3, D1, Pm1 and Pr1 decrease, while D'3, Pm3 and p'2 increase and vice versa.
The results of Tables 9 and 10 are similar to the results of Tables 7 and 8, except for the sensitivity analysis of b13 and b31. Wf, W3f, P1, P3, D1 and D'3 are moderately sensitive respect to the changes in parameters b13 and b31, while <1, Pm3, Pr1 and Pr2 are slightly sensitive respect to the changes in parameters b13 and b31. When b13 and b31 are decreased by 25 and 50 %, Wf, W3f, P1, Pf and p'2
increase, while D1, D'3, Pm1, Pm3 and Pr1 decrease and vice versa.
Some of the sensitivity analyses in Tables 3, 4, 5, 6, 7, 8, 9 and 10 are illustrated by Figs. 4, 5, 6, 7, 8, 9, 10, 11 and 12. Figures 4, 5, 6, 7, 8, 9, 10, 11 and 12 show the effect of some key parameters on optimal wholesale and retail prices and also on the profit of the chain.
Conclusion
We discussed the pricing problem of two complementary and substitutable products in a two-echelon supply chain under two scenarios where two manufacturers and one retailer are the members of each echelon. Under the first scenario, which leads to develop the first model, the same unit manufacturing costs for both echelons are supposed and in the second one we assume that the unit manufacturing costs of echelons are different which causes to leak demand from the echelon with higher unit manufacturing cost to the lower one. Two same complementary products
Table 4 The sensitivity analysis for the first models profit functions in first echelon of supply chain under MS-Bertrand policy
Parameters % Changes Optimal values % Changes in
pmi pm2 Pr1 pm1 pm2 Pr1
Ai = A2 -50 724.85 724.85 453.03 -80.86 -80.86 -80.86
-25 1956.36 1956.36 1222.73 -48.34 -48.34 -48.34
+25 6216.72 6216.72 3885.45 64.16 64.16 64.16
+50 9245.56 9245.56 5778.48 144.14 144.14 144.14
bll = b22 -50 5398.25 5398.25 2453.75 42.55 42.55 3.67
-25 4525.47 4525.47 2514.15 19.50 19.50 6.22
+25 3201.06 3201.06 2162.88 -15.47 -15.47 -8.62
+50 2736.00 2736.00 1954.29 -27.75 -27.75 -17.43
bl2 = b21 -50 5068.82 5068.82 3899.09 33.85 33.85 64.74
-25 4365.43 4365.43 3010.64 15.27 15.27 27.20
+25 3306.25 3306.25 1889.29 -12.69 -12.69 -20.18
+50 2902.98 2902.98 1527.88 -23.34 -23.34 -35.45
Cl = C2 -50 4275.15 4275.15 2671.97 12.89 12.89 12.89
-25 4027.37 4027.37 2517.10 6.35 6.35 6.35
+25 3553.99 3553.99 2221.25 -6.15 -6.15 -6.15
+50 3328.40 3328.40 2080.25 -12.11 -12.11 -12.11
Table 5 The sensitivity analysis for the first model in first echelon of supply chain under MS-Stackelberg policy
Parameters % Changes Optimal values % Changes in
Wf Wf P1 P2 D D2 Wf W2f P1 P2 D1 D2
A1 : = A2 -50 84.76 77.07 98.63 94.79 12.25 13.02 -47.55 -46.49 -48.97 -48.63 -56.25 -56.25
-25 123.17 110.55 145.96 139.65 20.13 21.39 -23.77 -23.24 -24.49 -24.31 -28.13 -28.13
+25 200 177.50 240.63 229.38 35.88 38.13 23.77 23.24 24.49 24.31 28.13 28.13
+50 238.41 210.98 287.96 274.24 43.75 46.49 47.55 46.49 48.97 48.63 56.25 56.25
bn = b22 -50 500.00 72.50 413.64 199.89 16.63 5.94 209.43 -49.66 113.9 8.33 -40.63 -80.05
-25 216.91 165.74 241.79 216.20 24.47 26.39 34.24 15.07 25.09 17.17 -12.61 -11.32
+25 132.80 124.63 163.70 159.61 29.81 31.13 -17.82 -13.47 -15.31 -13.50 6.45 4.63
+50 114.13 109.67 142.78 140.55 30.75 31.75 -29.37 -23.85 -26.13 -23.83 9.82 6.71
b12 = b21 -50 170.75 166.89 223.83 221.91 34.80 35.47 5.67 15.87 15.80 20.27 24.27 19.21
-25 164.59 155.47 206.43 201.87 31.36 32.62 1.86 7.95 6.80 9.41 12.01 9.61
+25 162.50 131.56 184.11 168.64 24.71 26.64 0.57 -8.65 -4.75 -8.60 -11.76 -10.47
+50 169.43 116.26 179.45 152.86 21.48 22.81 4.86 -19.28 -7.16 -17.15 -23.27 -23.33
C1 = C2 -50 157.62 138.96 191.31 181.98 29.75 31.62 -2.45 -3.51 -1.03 -1.37 6.25 6.25
-25 159.60 141.49 192.30 183.25 28.88 30.69 -1.23 -1.76 -0.51 -0.69 3.12 3.12
+25 163.57 146.55 194.28 185.78 27.13 28.83 1.226 1.757 0.513 0.686 -3.125 -3.125
+50 165.55 149.09 195.27 187.04 26.25 27.90 2.45 3.51 1.03 1.37 -6.25 -6.25
are supplied to the market by each echelon of chain to satisfy the customers' demand. The model is developed under price-sensitive and deterministic demand.
The main aim of this research is to analyze the pricing decisions of the members of chain for complementary and substitutable products with the different market powers under two scenarios. In this research, two solution algorithms including MS-Bertrand and MS-Stackelberg game-theoretic approaches are presented to survey the effects of
the different market powers on the optimal value of decision variables and also the total profit of the supply chain where the whole sale prices of manufacturers and the retail prices of retailers are the decision variables of the proposed models. Finally, a numerical example to show the applicability of the proposed models is presented and we found that the maximum profit of the whole supply chain is obtained under MS-Bertrand approach in both proposed models. For future works, the model can be extended under
Table 6 The sensitivity analysis for the first models profit functions in first echelon of supply chain under MS-Stackelberg policy
Parameters % Changes Optimal values % Changes in
pmi pm2 Pr1 pm1 pm2 Pr1
Ai = A2 -50 732.01 677.90 400.53 -80.86 -80.86 -80.86
-25 1975.69 1829.65 1081.02 -48.34 -48.34 -48.34
+25 6278.13 5814.06 3435.16 64.16 64.16 64.16
+50 9336.89 8646.73 5108.80 144.14 144.14 144.14
bll = b22 -50 7896.88 282.03 -679.44 106.49 -92.04 -132.47
-25 4695.84 3713.70 1940.40 22.79 4.86 -7.27
+25 3213.07 3101.82 2010.12 -15.98 -12.42 -3.94
+50 2740.76 2688.63 1861.40 -28.33 -24.09 -11.05
bl2 = b21 -50 5071.51 5033.06 3798.90 32.61 42.11 81.54
-25 4377.88 4255.48 2825.95 14.47 20.15 35.05
+25 3397.22 2838.89 1521.57 -11.17 -19.84 -27.29
+50 3103.05 2081.88 1050.48 -18.86 -41.22 -49.80
W -50 4317.38 3998.25 2362.31 12.89 12.89 12.89
-25 4067.15 3766.52 2225.39 6.35 6.35 6.35
+25 3589.10 3323.80 1963.82 -6.152 -6.152 -6.152
+50 3361.28 3112.82 1839.17 -12.11 -12.11 -12.11
Table 7 The sensitivity analysis for the second model between products 1 and 3 under MS-Bertrand policy
Parameters % Changes Optimal values % Changes in
wr wr P1 P3 D1 D3 wr w3r pr P3 D1 D3
A1 -50 268.66 360.37 378.45 513.72 54.89 76.68 -30.84 -13.21 -31.47 -13.41 -32.96 -13.88
-25 328.56 387.79 465.33 553.49 68.38 82.85 -15.42 -6.60 -15.73 -6.70 -16.48 -6.94
+25 448.35 442.62 639.08 633.04 95.37 95.21 15.42 6.60 15.73 6.70 16.48 6.94
+50 508.24 470.04 725.96 672.81 108.86 101.38 30.84 13.21 31.47 13.41 32.96 13.88
A3 -50 321.43 268.80 454.98 380.89 66.78 56.05 -17.25 -35.26 -17.61 -35.80 -18.44 -37.05
-25 354.94 342.00 503.59 487.08 74.33 72.54 -8.63 -17.63 -8.80 -17.90 -9.22 -18.52
+25 421.96 488.41 600.82 699.45 89.43 105.52 8.63 17.63 8.80 17.90 9.22 18.52
+50 455.48 561.61 649.43 805.63 96.98 122.01 17.25 35.26 17.61 35.80 18.44 37.05
b1 = b3 -50 646.03 678.53 905.73 953.91 103.88 110.15 66.31 63.42 64.02 60.79 26.88 23.73
-25 484.51 513.82 685.55 729.87 90.47 97.22 24.73 23.75 24.15 23.03 10.49 9.20
+25 324.78 349.41 462.63 500.88 75.82 83.31 -16.39 -15.85 -16.22 -15.57 -7.40 -6.43
+50 279.50 302.31 398.26 434.05 71.26 79.05 -28.05 -27.19 -27.88 -26.84 -12.97 -11.21
b13 = b31 -50 424.88 466.87 615.20 679.55 66.61 74.44 9.38 12.44 11.41 14.54 -18.64 -16.39
-25 405.98 438.69 582.12 632.26 74.86 82.27 4.51 5.66 5.42 6.57 -8.57 -7.60
+25 372.31 394.90 525.30 560.05 87.97 94.96 -4.16 -4.89 -4.87 -5.60 7.44 6.66
+50 357.45 376.97 501.05 531.16 93.34 100.22 -7.98 -9.21 -9.26 -10.47 14.00 12.57
C1 -50 381.99 414.02 548.46 591.55 83.24 88.76 -1.66 -0.28 -0.68 -0.29 1.66 -0.30
-25 385.22 414.61 550.33 592.41 82.56 88.90 -0.83 -0.14 -0.34 -0.14 0.83 -0.15
+25 391.69 415.80 554.08 594.12 81.20 89.16 0.83 0.14 0.34 0.14 --0.83 0.15
+50 394.92 416.39 555.95 594.98 80.52 89.30 1.66 0.28 0.68 0.29 -1.66 0.30
C3 -50 387.51 410.03 550.83 590.27 81.66 90.12 -0.24 -1.25 -0.25 -0.51 -0.26 1.22
-25 387.98 412.62 551.52 591.76 81.77 89.57 -0.12 -0.62 -0.12 -0.25 -0.13 0.61
+25 388.93 417.79 552.89 594.76 81.98 88.49 0.12 0.62 0.12 0.25 0.13 -0.61
+50 389.40 420.38 553.58 596.26 82.09 87.94 0.24 1.25 0.25 0.51 0.26 -1.22
Table 8 The sensitivity analysis for the second models profit functions between products 1 and 3 under MS-Bertrand policy
Parameters % Changes Optimal values % Changes in
p!nl <3 <1 pr2 <3 <1 pr2
Ai -50 l3,375.09 26,097.77 l0,684.74 2l,l46.28 -55.05 -25.83 -55.39 -25.65
-25 20,758.53 30,47l.97 l6,658.45 24,659.28 -30.24 -l3.39 -30.45 -l3.30
+25 40,374.l3 40,236.60 32,569.53 32,494.82 35.67 l4.36 35.97 l4.25
+50 52,606.30 45,627.02 42,506.89 36,8l7.36 76.78 29.68 77.46 29.45
A3 -50 l9,794.57 l3,944.55 l5,970.80 ll,l98.29 -33.48 -60.37 -33.33 -60.63
-25 24,523.38 23,357.54 l9,760.54 l8,833.38 -l7.59 -33.6l -l7.50 -33.78
+25 35,499.05 49,426.68 28,549.32 40,024.55 l9.29 40.48 l9.l9 40.72
+50 4l,745.9l 66,082.84 33,548.37 53,580.65 40.28 87.82 40.06 88.38
bl — b3 -50 64,5l3.33 72,539.66 37,524.l4 42,924.35 ll6.79 l06.l7 56.65 50.92
-25 4l,570.0l 48,0l0.27 28,732.7l 33,594.07 39.69 36.45 l9.95 l8.ll
+25 22,728.34 27,442.l3 20,996.8l 25,208.06 -23.62 -22.0l -12.34 -ll.37
+50 l8,l35.l8 22,3l5.55 l9,008.92 23,003.5l -39.06 -36.58 -20.64 -l9.l2
bl3 = b3l -50 26,636.86 33,264.08 23,223.27 28,42l.l5 -10.49 -5.46 -3.05 -0.07
-25 28,5l9.45 34,444.l9 23,73l.ll 28,5l4.0l -4.l6 -2.ll -0.93 -0.25
+25 30,552.90 35,600.53 24,004.62 28,27l.89 2.67 l.l8 0.2l 0.60
+50 3l,030.40 35,775.83 23,948.88 28,042.33 4.28 l.68 0.02 l.4l
Cl -50 30,754.43 34,974.6l 24,843.3l 28,258.l9 3.35 -0.60 3.72 -0.65
-25 30,254.27 35,079.69 24,396.29 28,350.08 l.67 -0.30 1.85 -0.32
+25 29,266.25 35,290.3l 23,5l4.57 28,534.32 -l.65 0.30 -l.83 0.32
+50 28,778.38 35,395.86 23,079.87 28,626.67 -3.29 0.60 -3.65 0.65
C3 -50 29,603.45 36,049.64 23,8l8.34 29,2l6.22 -0.52 2.46 -0.56 2.72
-25 29,680.78 35,6l5.97 23,885.8l 28,827.86 -0.26 l.23 -0.28 l.36
+25 29,835.74 34,756.49 24,02l.04 28,059.03 0.26 -1.22 0.28 -l.35
+50 29,9l3.37 34,330.69 24,088.80 27,678.55 0.52 -2.43 0.57 -2.68
stochastic demand and also considering competing retailers can develop and enhance our models.
Funding The first author would like to thank the financial support of the University of Tehran for this research under Grant Number 30015-1-02.
Open Access This article is distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License (http://crea tivecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/), which permits unrestricted use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided you give appropriate credit to the original author(s) and the source, provide a link to the Creative Commons license, and indicate if changes were made.
Appendix 1: Notations of the first model
The notations employed to solving the first model which is developed under the first scenario are as follows:
2^1 - A2(bl2 + b2l)
2bllb22 - bl2(bl2 + b21 )
F6 —
4bllb22 (bl2 + b2l)2
(75) U3
4bllb22 - (bl2 + b2l)2
2b2lb22 - -b22 (bl2 + b2l )
4bllb22 (bl2 + b2l)2
2bllA2 - Al(bl2 ^ b2l)
4bllb22 - - (bl2 + b2l)2
2bllbl2 - bll (bl2 + b2l )
4bllb22 (bl2 + b2l)2
2bllb22 - b2l (bl2 + b2l )
4bllb22 (bl2 + b2l)2
2b44A3 - A4(b34- M43)
4b33b44 - - (b34 + b43 )2
2b33b44 - -b34(b34 + b43)
4b33b44 - (b34 + b43)2
2b43b44 - - b44 (b34 + b43)
4b33b44 - (b34 + b43)2
(80) (8l) (82) (83)
Table 9 The sensitivity analysis for the second model between products 1 and 3 under MS-Stackelberg policy
Parameters % Changes Optimal values % Changes in
W3* pi P3 D'i D3 W3* pi P3 Di D3
Ai -50 270.90 372.57 38i.69 520.79 55.39 74.ii -30.72 -13.23 -3i.35 -13.41 -32.82 -i3.88
-25 330.97 400.97 468.83 56i.i4 68.93 80.08 -i5.36 -6.6i -15.67 -6.7i -16.41 -6.94
+25 45i.i2 457.78 643.ii 64i.82 95.99 92.02 30.72 i3.23 3i.35 13.41 32.82 i3.88
+50 5ii.i9 486.i8 730.25 682.i7 i09.53 97.99 30.72 i3.23 3i.35 13.41 32.82 i3.88
A3 -50 323.06 277.72 457.35 386.06 67.i5 54.i7 -i7.39 -35.32 -17.74 -35.8i -18.57 -37.05
-25 357.05 353.55 506.66 493.77 74.80 70.ii -8.69 -i7.66 -8.87 -17.91 -9.29 -i8.52
+25 425.04 505.2i 605.27 709.i9 90.i2 i0i.99 8.69 i7.66 8.87 17.91 9.29 i8.52
+50 459.03 58i.04 654.58 8i6.89 97.78 ii7.93 i7.39 35.32 17.74 35.8i i8.57 37.05
bi = b3 -50 659.56 730.40 924.92 987.05 i06.i4 i02.66 68.67 70.ii 66.36 64.10 28.72 i9.30
-25 489.86 538.79 693.24 744.92 9i.52 92.76 25.27 25.48 24.69 23.85 i0.99 7.79
+25 326.2i 358.32 464.7i 505.90 76.i8 8i.i7 -i6.58 -i6.55 -16.41 -i5.89 -7.62 -5.67
+50 280.35 308.32 399.52 437.37 7i.50 77.43 -28.3i -28.i9 -28.14 -27.28 -13.29 -10.01
bi3 = b3i -50 425.64 473.27 6i6.32 682.99 66.74 73.40 8.85 i0.22 10.86 i3.55 -i9.07 -14.70
-25 407.58 449.i0 584.46 638.08 75.i7 80.32 4.23 4.59 5.13 6.09 -8.84 -6.66
+25 375.95 4i2.49 530.55 570.55 88.89 90.89 -3.86 -3.93 -4.57 -5.i4 7.80 5.62
+50 362.i5 397.60 507.77 543.80 94.66 95.03 -7.39 -7.40 -8.67 -9.59 i4.79 i0.43
Ci -50 384.57 428.i5 552.2i 599.74 83.82 85.79 -i.66 -0.29 -0.68 -0.29 1.65 -0.30
-25 387.8i 428.76 554.09 600.6i 83.i4 85.92 -0.83 -0.i4 -0.34 -0.14 0.82 -0.15
+25 394.28 429.99 557.85 602.35 8i.78 86.i8 0.83 0.i4 0.34 0.14 -0.82 0.15
+50 397.52 430.60 559.73 603.22 8i.i0 86.3i i.66 0.29 0.68 0.29 -i.65 0.30
C3 -50 390.i3 424.38 554.64 598.58 82.25 87.i0 -0.23 -i.i6 -0.24 -0.48 -0.25 1.22
-25 390.59 426.88 555.30 600.03 82.36 86.58 -0.i2 -0.58 -0.12 -0.24 -0.i2 0.61
+25 39i.50 43i.88 556.63 602.93 82.56 85.52 0.i2 0.58 0.12 0.24 0.12 -0.6i
+50 39i.96 434.38 557.29 604.38 82.67 85.00 0.23 i.i6 0.24 0.48 0.25 -1.22
U4 2b33A4 - A3(b34 + b43) (84) G2 = A4 + b44(C4U6 - U4) + b43(C4U3 - Ui) (96)
4b33b44 - -(b34 + b43 )2 G3 = b33U3 + b34U6 (97)
U5 2b33b34 - -b33(b34 + b43) (85) G4 = 2(b33U2 + b34U5) (98)
4b33b44 -(b34 + b43)2 G5 = b44U5 + b43U2 (99)
U6 _ 2b33b44 - -b43(b34 + b43) (86) G6 = 2(b44U6 + b43 U3 ) (100)
4b33b44 -(b34 + b43)2 G7 = (A3 - b33Ui - b34U4)G6 - G3G2
El = Ai + bii(CiF2 - Fi) + ^12(^1^5 - F4) E2 = A2 + b22(C2F6 - F4) + b2i (C2F3 - Fi) E3 = biiF3 + bi2F6 E4 = 2(biiF2 + bi2F5) E5 = b22F5 + b^2 E6 = 2(b22F6 + b2iF3) E7 = (A3 - biiFi - bi2F4)E6
- E3 E5
Eg = E4E6 - 2E3E5
Gi = A3 + b33(C3 U2 - Ui) + b34(C3U5 - U4)
- G3G5
G4G6 — 2G3G5
Appendix 2: Notations of the second model
The notations employed to solve the second model which is developed under the second scenario are as follows:
2Ai(b3 + Li)+ Li A3 4(bi + Li)(b3 + Li)- Li
Table 10 The sensitivity analysis for the second models profit functions between products 1 and 3 under MS-Stackelberg policy
Parameters % Changes Optimal values % Changes in
<1 <3 <1 pr2 <3 <1 pr2
Ai -50 i3,62i.34 26,i29.09 i0,872.5i i9,80i.64 -54.87 -25.83 -55.22 -25.65
-25 2i,089.82 30,508.54 i6,9ii.46 23,09i.i8 -30.13 -13.39 -30.35 -13.30
+25 40,904.68 40,284.89 32,975.3i 30,428.27 76.42 29.68 77.ii 29.45
+50 53,25i.06 45,68i.78 43,000.22 34,475.82 76.42 29.68 77.ii 29.45
A3 -50 20,0i3.i6 i3,96i.28 i6,i37.56 i0,485.95 -33.70 -60.37 -33.53 -60.63
-25 24,838.40 23,385.57 20,00i.i7 i7,635.55 -17.71 -33.6i -17.62 -33.78
+25 36,050.76 49,486.00 28,97i.2i 37,479.43 19.44 40.48 i9.33 40.72
+50 42,437.88 66,i62.i4 34,077.64 50,i73.70 40.60 87.82 40.36 88.39
bi = b3 -50 67,355.56 72,928.53 38,846.42 38,i70.52 123.15 i07.02 60.00 43.32
-25 42,543.7i 48,i2i.73 29,292.42 30,943.8i 40.95 36.60 20.65 16.18
+25 22,945.30 27,46i.i8 2i,230.29 23,803.i6 -23.98 -22.05 -12.56 -10.63
+50 i8,257.67 22,325.24 i9,i99.80 2i,8i7.2i -39.51 -36.62 -20.92 -18.08
bi3 = b3i -50 26,737.5i 33,270.70 23,404.89 27,2i7.93 -11.42 -5.55 -3.60 2.19
-25 28,759.93 34,464.48 23,976.00 27,002.80 -4.72 -2.i6 -1.25 1.39
+25 3i,i96.96 35,672.i4 24,422.05 26,i90.i4 3.36 i.26 0.59 -1.66
+50 3i,9i3.39 35,882.98 24,463.99 25,7i6.92 5.73 i.86 0.76 -3.44
Ci -50 3i,i86.24 35,0i6.58 25,i73.85 26,46i.ii 3.32 -0.60 3.69 -0.65
-25 30,683.2i 35,i2i.78 24,724.4i 26,547.i7 1.65 -0.30 1.83 -0.32
+25 29,689.42 35,332.66 23,837.8i 26,7i9.73 -1.64 0.30 -1.82 0.32
+50 29,i98.66 35,438.33 23,400.65 26,806.23 -3.27 0.60 -3.62 0.65
C3 -50 30,033.62 36,092.90 24,i47.48 27,358.45 -0.50 2.46 -0.54 2.72
-25 30,i08.90 35,658.7i 24,2i3.22 26,994.69 -0.25 i.23 -0.27 1.36
+25 30,259.74 34,798.20 24,344.98 26,274.54 0.25 -1.22 0.27 -1.35
+50 30,335.30 34,37i.89 24,4ii.00 25,9i8.i6 0.50 -2.43 0.54 -2.69
100 50 0
" Wi ■ w2
Pi ■p2
Fig. 4 Changes of optimal prices with respect to A1 = A2 for the first model under MS-Bertrand policy
■ Wl
■ W2
0.25 0.375 0.5 0.625 0.75
Al = 022
Fig. 5 Changes of optimal prices with respect to b11 = b22 for the first model under MS-Bertrand policy
Li(bs + Li)
"4(bi + Li)(b3 + Li)- L?
2(bi + Li )(b3 + Li ) 4(bi + Li)(b3 + Li)- Li
2A2 (b4 + L2) + L2A4 4(b2 + L2)(b4 + L2)- L2
L2(b4 + L2) 4(b2 + L2)(b4 + L2)- L2
(i06) (i07)
■ nml
■ nm2 7Trl
800 700 600 500 400 300 200 100 0
180 Ai
■ Wt
Pi ■p3
Fig. 6 Changes of maximum profits with respect to Ai = A2 for the Fig. 9 Changes of optimal prices with respect to Ai for the second first model under MS-Bertrand policy model under MS-Bertrand policy
—♦— w,
-m- W2 1000
Pi 800
-x- P2 dJ
0.15 0.225 0.3 0.375 0.45
Pl2 = 021
Fig. 7 Changes of optimal prices with respect to bi2 = P21 for the first model under MS-Stackelberg policy
w3 Pi p,
ßi=ßz
Fig. 10 Changes of optimal prices with respect to bi = b3 for the second model under MS-Bertrand policy
4 \-i \-i k
■ 1-1 1-1 1-1 1 1 1-
w2 35000
Pi 30000
p, 25000
Ci = Cn
s S-> i-) (-> i-> -
'-1 L j ' J L
• nml
• fr2
31.25 37.5
r. „ ™ c .. , ^ c a ^ Fig. 11 Changes of maximum profits with respect to C1 for the
Fig. 8 Changes of optimal prices with respect to C1 = C2 for the first " ° 1 1 1
■ . j nic i iu r second model under MS-Stackelberg policy
model under MS-Stackelberg policy b r J
2(b2 + L )(b4 + L2 )
4(b2 + ¿2)(b4 + ¿2)- ¿2
2As(bi + L) + Li Ai 4(bi + Li)(b3 + Li)- Li
¿i(bi + ¿i) 4(bi + Li)(b3 + Li)- ¿i
2A4(b2 + L2) + L2A2 4(b2 + L2)(b4 + L2)- L2
L2(b2 + L2 ) ~4(b2 + L2)(b4 + L2)- L2
Ni = Ai - biKi - Li(Ki - K7) + Ci(biK3 + LiK3 - LiK8)
Fig. 12 Changes of maximum demands with respect to C3 for the
second model under MS-Stackelberg policy
N2 = A3 - &K7 - Ll(*7 - Kl)
+ C3(b3K3 + L1K3 - L1K2) (114)
N3 = b1 K2 + L1K2 - L1K3 (115)
N4 = 2(b1 K3 + L1K3 - L1K8) (116)
N5 = b3Kg + L1K - L1K3 (117)
N6 = 2GS3K3 + L1K3 - L1K2) (118)
N7 = A2 - - L2(K4 - K9)
+ C2(b2K6 + L2K6 - L2K10) (119)
Ng = A4 - &K9 - L2(K9 - K4)
+ C4 (b*6 + L2K6 - L2K5 ) (120)
N9 = b2K5 + L2K5 - L2K6 (121)
N10 = 2(&K + L2K6 - L2K10) (122)
N11 = b4K10 + L2K10 - L2K6 (123)
N12 = 2(&K + L2K6 - L2K5) (124)
N13 = (A3 - &K7 - L1OK7 - K1))N4 - N1N5
+ [N4p - N3N5J C3 (125)
N14 = N4N6 - 2N3N5 (126) N15 = (A3 - &K9 - L2(K9 - K4))N10 - N7N11
+ - N9N11] C4 (127)
N16 = N10N12 - 2N9N11 (128)
References
Boyaci T, Gallego G (2002) Coordinating pricing and inventory replenishment policies for one wholesaler and one or more geographically dispersed retailers. Int J Prod Econ 77(2):95—111 Chen X, Simchi-Levi D (2004a) Coordinating inventory control and pricing strategies with random demand and fixed ordering cost: the infinite horizon case. Math Oper Res 29:698-723
Chen X, Simchi-Levi D (2004b) Coordinating inventory control and pricing strategies with random demand and fixed ordering cost: the finite horizon case. Oper Res 52:887-896 Chen X, Simchi-Levi D (2006) Coordinating inventory control and pricing strategies: the continuous review model. Oper Res Lett 34(3):323-332
Chen Y, Ray S, Song Y (2006) Optimal pricing and inventory control policy in periodic-review systems with fixed ordering cost and lost sales. Naval Res Logist 53:117-136 Chen YC, Fang SC, Wen UP (2013) Pricing policies for substi-tutable products in a supply chain with Internet and traditional channels. Eur J Oper Res 224(3):542-551 Dada M, Srikanth K (1987) Pricing policies for quantity discounts.
Manag Sci 33(1):1247-1252 Elmaghraby W, Keskinocak P (2003) Dynamic pricing in the presence of inventory considerations: research overview, current practices, and future directions. Manag Sci 49(10):1287-1309 Fei W, Du M, Luo G (2015) Optimal prices and associated factors of product with substitution for one supplier and multiple retailers supply chain. Proc Comput Sci 60:1271-1280 Giri BC, Sharma S (2014) Manufacturer's pricing strategy in a two-level supply chain with competing retailers and advertising cost dependent demand. Econ Model 38(2):102-111 Gurler U, Yilmaz A (2010) Inventory and coordination issues with
two substitutable products. Appl Math Model 34(3):539-551 Hsieh CC, Wu CH (2009) Coordinated decisions for substi-tutable products in a common retailer supply chain. Eur J Oper Res 196(1):273-288 Hsieh CC, Chang YL, Wu CH (2014) Competitive pricing and ordering decisions in a multiple-channel supply chain. Int J Prod Econ 154:156-165 Kim DS, Lee WJ (1998) Optimal joint pricing and lot sizing with
fixed and variable capacity. Eur J Oper Res 109(1):212-227 Mahmoodi A, Eshghi K (2014) Price competition in duopoly supply
chains with stochastic demand. J Manuf Syst (in press) Maihami R, Karimi B (2014) Optimizing the pricing and replenishment policy for non-instantaneous deteriorating items with stochastic demand and promotional efforts. Comput Oper Res 51:302-312
Mukhopadhyay SK, Yue X, Zhu X (2011) A Stackelberg model of pricing of complementary goods under information asymmetry. Int J Prod Econ 134(2):424-433 Panda S, Modak NM, Sana SS, Basu M (2015) Pricing and replenishment policies in dual-channel supply chain under continuous unit cost decrease. Appl Math Comput 256:913-929 Shavandi H, Mahlooji H, Nosratian NE (2012) A constrained multi-product pricing and inventory control problem. Appl Soft Comput 12(8):2454-2461 Sinha S, Sarmah S (2010) Coordination and price competition in a duopoly common retailer supply chain. Comput Ind Eng 59(2):280-295
Soon W (2011) A review of multi-product pricing models. Appl Math
Comput 217(21):8149-8165 Starr M, Rubinson J (1978) A loyalty group segmentation model for
brand purchasing simulation. J Mark Res 15(3):378-383 Taleizadeh AA, Noori-daryan M (2014) Pricing, manufacturing and inventory policies for raw material in a three-level supply chain. Int J Syst Sci 47(4):919-931 Taleizadeh AA, Noori-daryan M, Cardenas-Barron LE (2014) Joint optimization of price, replenishment frequency, replenishment cycle and production rate in vendor managed inventory system with deteriorating items. Int J Prod Econ 159:285-295 Tang CS, Yin R (2007) Joint ordering and pricing strategies for managing substitutable products. Prod Oper Manag 16(1):138-153
Wang L, Zhao J, Wei J (2014) Pricing decisions of two complementary products in a fuzzy environment. Math Probl Eng 2014:1-8, Art ID 729287. doi:10.1155/2014/729287 Wei J, Zhao J (2011) Pricing decisions with retail competition in a fuzzy closed-loop supply chain. Expert Syst Appl 38(9): 11209-11216
Wei J, Zhao J, Li Y (2013) Pricing decisions for complementary products with firms' different market powers. Eur J Oper Res 224(3):507-519
Wei J, Zhao J, Li Y (2015) Price and warranty period decisions for complementary products with horizontal firms' cooperation/ noncooperation strategies. J Clean Prod 105:86-102. doi:10. 1016/j.jclepro.2014.09.059 Xiao T, Jin J, Chen G, Shi J, Xie M (2010) Ordering, wholesale pricing and lead-time decisions in a three-stage supply chain under demand uncertainty. Comput Ind Eng 59(4):840-852 Yan R, Bandyopadhyay S (2011) The profit benefits of bundle pricing of complementary products. J Retail Consum Serv 18(4): 355-361
Yu J, Ma S (2013) Impact of decision sequence of pricing and quality investment in decentralized assembly system. J Manuf Syst 32(4):664-679
Yue X, Mukhopadhyay SK, Zhu X (2006) A Bertrand model of pricing of complementary goods under information asymmetry. J Bus Res 59(10):1182-1192 Zhang J, Chiang WYK, Liang L (2014) Strategic pricing with reference effects in a competitive supply chain. Omega 44:126-135
Zhao J, Tang W, Wei J (2012a) Pricing decision for substi-tutable products with retail competition in a fuzzy environment. Int J Prod Econ 135(1):144-153 Zhao J, Tang W, Zhao R, Wei J (2012b) Pricing decisions for substitutable products with a common retailer in fuzzy environments. Eur J Oper Res 216(2):409-419 Zhao J, Wei J, Li Y (2014) Pricing decisions for substitutable products in a two-echelon supply chain with firm different channel powers. Int J Prod Econ 153(4):243-252