Scholarly article on topic 'A model based on Copula Theory for sustainable and social responsible investments'

A model based on Copula Theory for sustainable and social responsible investments Academic research paper on "Economics and business"

CC BY-NC-ND
0
0
Share paper
Academic journal
Revista de Contabilidad
OECD Field of science
Keywords
{"Sustainable and social responsible investment" / Copulas / "Prospect Theory" / "Goal Programming" / "Fuzzy Set Theory" / "Inversión Sostenible y Socialmente Responsable" / Cópulas / "Teoría de la Prospección" / "Programación por Metas" / "Teoría de los Subconjuntos Difusos"}

Abstract of research paper on Economics and business, author of scientific article — Amelia Bilbao-Terol, Mar Arenas-Parra, Verónica Cañal-Fernández

Abstract In this paper, a model is proposed that allows us to obtain a portfolio made up of sustainable and socially responsible (SR) investment funds. This portfolio tracks the one that investors might have chosen if they had not taken into account social, ethical and ecological (SEE) issues in their investment decisions. Therefore, in the first stage, reference portfolio exclusively made up of conventional funds is obtained. For the construction of the conventional portfolio the Prospect Theory has been used: net profits as the financial objective and error function as the utility function. In the second stage, a portfolio consisting exclusively of SR-funds is built. To do so, the reference portfolio is used as an ideal point, with the objectives of the SR-investor being the relative wealth with respect to the reference portfolio and the SEE quality of the portfolio. The relative wealth will be manipulated by a downside-risk measure, the Conditional Value at Risk (CVaR), and the periodic values of the portfolio. The second objective is the SR Quality of the portfolio, taking into account the personal values of a particular investor. This is built using Fuzzy Set Theory tools. We are faced with a multi-objective problem which is solved by using Goal Programming methodology. The estimation of both conventional and SR markets has been carried out by a semi-parametric approach by using the Copula Theory for modeling the dependence structure of the assets’ returns. The approach has been applied to a set of 38 conventional and 12 ethical funds domiciled in Spain.

Academic research paper on topic "A model based on Copula Theory for sustainable and social responsible investments"

'"I'WW^^B AIIIIII .E IN PRESS

Revista de Contabilidad - Spanish Accounting Review xxx (xx) (2015) xxx-xxx

REVISTA DE CONTABILIDAD SPANISH ACCOUNTING REVIEW

www.elsevier.es/rcsar

A model based on Copula Theory for sustainable and social responsible investments

Amelia Bilbao-Terola*, Mar Arenas-Parra3, Verónica Canal-Fernándezb

a University of Oviedo, Department of Quantitative Economics, Oviedo, Asturias, Spain b University of Oviedo, Department of Economics, Oviedo, Asturias, Spain

ARTICLE INFO

ABSTRACT

Article history: Received 27 March 2014 Accepted 8 January 2015 Available online xxx

JEL classification:

Keywords:

Sustainable and social responsible

investment

Copulas

Prospect Theory Goal Programming Fuzzy Set Theory

In this paper, a model is proposed that allows us to obtain a portfolio made up of sustainable and socially responsible (SR) investment funds. This portfolio tracks the one that investors might have chosen if they had not taken into account social, ethical and ecological (SEE) issues in their investment decisions. Therefore, in the first stage, reference portfolio exclusively made up of conventional funds is obtained. For the construction of the conventional portfolio the Prospect Theory has been used: net profits as the financial objective and error function as the utility function. In the second stage, a portfolio consisting exclusively of SR-funds is built. To do so, the reference portfolio is used as an ideal point, with the objectives of the SR-investor being the relative wealth with respect to the reference portfolio and the SEE quality of the portfolio. The relative wealth will be manipulated by a downside-risk measure, the Conditional Value at Risk (CVaR), and the periodic values of the portfolio. The second objective is the SR Quality of the portfolio, taking into account the personal values of a particular investor. This is built using Fuzzy Set Theory tools. We are faced with a multi-objective problem which is solved by using Goal Programming methodology. The estimation of both conventional and SR markets has been carried out by a semi-parametric approach by using the Copula Theory for modeling the dependence structure of the assets' returns. The approach has been applied to a set of 38 conventional and 12 ethical funds domiciled in Spain.

© 2014 ASEPUC. Published by Elsevier España, S.L.U. This is an open access article under the CC BY-NC-ND license (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc-nd/4.0/).

Un modelo basado en la teoría de cópulas para la inversión sostenible y socialmente responsable

RESUMEN

Códigos JEL:

Palabras clave:

Inversión Sostenible y Socialmente

Responsable

Cópulas

Teoría de la Prospección Programación por Metas Teoría de los Subconjuntos Difusos

El modelo que se propone permite obtener una cartera formada por fondos de inversión sostenibles y socialmente responsables (SR). Esta cartera sigue (tracking) a la cartera que hubiese elegido el inversor si no tuviera en cuenta valores sociales, éticos y ecológicos (SEE) en sus decisiones de inversión. Por tanto, la primera etapa del modelo consiste en obtener la cartera de referencia formada exclusivamente por fondos convencionales. Para la construcción de esta cartera se utiliza la Teoría de la Prospección: beneficios netos como objetivo financiero y la función de error como función de utilidad. En la segunda etapa, se construye una cartera formada exclusivamente fondos SR. Para ello, se utiliza la cartera de referencia como un punto ideal siendo los objetivos del inversor socialmente responsable la riqueza relativa respecto de la cartera de referencia y la calidad SEE de la cartera. Por tanto, se tiene un objetivo aleatorio -la riqueza relativa- que será manipulado mediante su Valor en Riesgo Condicional (CVaR) que es una medida de riesgo inferior, es decir, tiene en cuenta las peores pérdidas de la cartera, y los valores periódicos de la cartera. El segundo objetivo está referido a la calidad SR de la cartera atendiendo las

* Corresponding author. E-mail address: ameliab@uniovi.es (A. Bilbao-Terol).

http://dx.doi.Org/10.1016/j.rcsar.2015.01.003

1138-4891/© 2014 ASEPUC. Published by Elsevier España, S.L.U. This is an open access article under the CC BY-NC-ND license (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc-nd/4.0/).

^llHW^^B IIIII.E IN PRESS

2 A. Bilbao-Terol et al./ Revista de Contabilidad - Spanish Accounting Review xxx (xx) (2015) xxx-xxx

creencias y valores personales de un inversor específico; se construye aplicando herramientas de la teoría de subconjuntos borrosos. Nos enfrentamos a un problema multi-objetivo que se resuelve mediante la Programación por Metas. La estimación de los mercados, convencional y SR, ha sido llevada a cabo mediante un enfoque semi-paramétrico utilizando la Teoría de Cópulas para modelar la estructura de dependencia de las rentabilidades de los activos. El modelo se ha implementado utilizando como mercado 38 fondos de inversión convencionales y 12 fondos éticos españoles.

© 2014 ASEPUC. Publicado por Elsevier España, S.L.U. Este es un artículo Open Access bajo la licencia CC

BY-NC-ND (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc-nd/4.0/).

1. Introduction

In a portfolio selection process, an investor seeks the combination of assets that best meets her needs in conditions of uncertainty. Therefore, in orderto determine the optimum portfolio the investor needs to model, estimate, evaluate and manage such uncertainty. Under certain hypotheses, it is possible to estimate the parameters of the market which are necessary for the model, and afterwards to solve the optimization problem. In general, the investor focuses on a function of the portfolio value at the end of the holding period. The return and the profit-and-loss of the portfolio are examples of such functions.

The most popular approach for the selection of portfolios is the mean-variance model suggested by Markowitz (1952,1959), where the investor tries to maximize her expected return for a fixed level of variance and within a set of investment constraints.

Modern Portfolio Theory (MPT) considers that investors can benefit from diversification by investing in financial assets with lower correlations. In MPT it is assumed that the financial returns follow a multivariate normal distribution. Therefore, the dependence between financial returns is described by the linear correlation coefficient and efficient portfolios are given by the traditional mean variance optimization program. However the variance has been criticized because it is a symmetric measure and treats downside risk and upside risk in the same way while the investors assign greater importance to downside risk than to upside risk (Ang, Chen, & Xing, 2006; Post & van Vliet, 2004).

Recently, there is a growing interest for the use of risk measures which taking into account the worst losses. Value at Risk (VaR)1 and Conditional Value at Risk (CVaR)2 have emerged as pertinent risk measures in finance and have found supporters in the financial community (Kaminski, Czupryna, & Szapiro, 2009; Krokhmal, Palmquist, & Uryasev, 2002; Meucci, 2007). The Basel Committee on Banking Supervision (Basel Committee on Banking Supervision, 2001,2011) validated these new tools and enforced its use among financial institutions to monitor the riskiness of their investment policies. In addition, VaR has been criticized for not being a coherent risk measure (for more details, see Artzner, Delbaen, Eber, & Heath, 1999; Gilboa, 2009; McNeil, Frey, & Embrechts, 2005). For this reason, we use the CVaR as downside risk measure instead of the VaR.

For solving the portfolio selection problem, it is necessary to carry out three tasks. Firstly, to model the market, that is, to determine a random model to generate the asset prices at the investment horizon. In order to address this point we have used Copula Theory. It was introduced by Sklar (1959) but was not applied in finance until 1999 (for a deep description of the

1 VaRa(X) is defined as the maximum expected loss on an investment over a specified horizon at a given confidence level a

VaRc(X) = sup{x/P[X > x] > a}.

2 CVaR„(X) at confidence level a is defined as the conditional expected loss under the condition that it exceeds the VaRa(X) : CVaRa(X) = E[X/X> VaRa(X)].

mathematical and statistical foundations of copulas, see Joe, 1997; Nelsen, 1999, and for a host of empirical applications of them, see Cherubini, Luciano, & Vecchiato, 2004; Jondeau, Poon, & Rockinger, 2007; McNeil et al., 2005). Sklar's theorem states that any multi-variate distribution can be factored into the marginal cumulative distributions and a copula function describing the dependence between the components. An important advantage of copula lies in separating marginal distributions and dependence structure from joint distribution. Another good feature of copula functions is that they allow for different degrees of tail dependence: the upper tail dependence exists when there is a positive probability of positive outliers occurring jointly while the lower tail dependence is a negative probability of negative outliers occurring jointly. In particular, we consider t-copulas for their easy handling for simulation.

Secondly, to define optimality taking into consideration the investor's profile. This question reveals the difficulty in interpreting optimality under uncertainty. For this, it is necessary to use suitable surrogates on the real line of the investor's objectives, called "risk measures" in the context of cost or loss. Then, the question of which properties should verify the risk measures appears. These properties are known in the literature as "risk measure coherence" (Artzner et al., 1999). Lastly, to calculate an optimum portfolio, that is, to determine exactly or with a good approximation a portfolio which best fits the investor's profile. In most situations exact solutions are unattainable because analytical solutions do not exist due to numerical problems associated with the non-convexity of the problem; therefore, it is necessary to appeal to approximations.

In recent years business increasingly has been viewed as a major cause of social, environmental and economic problems. The instances of corporate scams and scandals have made that the investors bear in mind the quality of governance of companies and responsibility of their conduct (Gupta, Mehlawat, & Saxena, 2013). In this way, the investors are becoming conscious of the desirability of sustainable and responsible evaluation of the financial assets. Sustainable and Responsible Investing (SRI) refers to an investment process that, along with the traditional financial analysis, integrates the analysis of a company's social responsibility in pursuit of enhanced long-term returns. SRI provides a comprehensive way to assess a company's real value by including both corporate responsibility and sustainability measures in a company's valuation (EUROSIF, 2012).

This investment approach attracts an important number of people who wish their investments to be in accordance with their morality. SRI includes one or more of the following strategies in the search for, selection and follow-up of a portfolio: the exclusion of companies or "harmful" sectors (such as armaments, tobacco, alcohol etc.) to society (negative screening), positive filters in order to identify companies who enjoy a good reputation for issues such as the environmental protection, fair labor practices, quality of products, and worthy relationships regarding their presence in other countries (positive screening), investment in best in class companies in environmental and social performance, and communication and interaction with companies about their environmental, social and corporate governance actions by means of the exercise of political rights inherent in the ownership of enterprises (constructive engagement or ethical overlay) (Renneboog, Ter Horst, & Zhang,

'"I'WW^^B ARTICLE IN PRESS

A. Bilbao-Terol etal./ Revista de Contabilidad - Spanish Accounting Review xxx (xx) (2015) xxx-xxx 3

2008a). There is increasing demand for business transparency; so companies should measure, report, and improve their social, environmental, and economic performance. However, determining how social and financial performances are connected is complicated due to the lack of consensus of measurement methodology concerning to corporate social responsibility. There are a lot of researches focused on the analysis of companies for their environmental, social or governance performance and their relationship with the financial performance, but the results obtained have not been conclusive. For example, Bello (2005) compares the performance of sustainable and conventional funds and shows that there is no significant under or overperformance of sustainable funds. Kempf and Osthoff (2007) do not observe statistical significant outperformance of high-rated companies over low-rated companies for the diversity, human rights, and product screen. Galema, Plantinga, and Scholtens (2008) consider the impact of SRI on stock returns and conclude that SRI has a significant impact on the stock returns. Derwall and Koedijk (2009) evaluate the performance of socially responsible bond and balanced funds relative to matched samples of conventional funds, over the period 1987-2003. Using multi-index performance evaluation models, they show that the average SRI bond fund performed similar to conventional funds. Statman and Glushkov (2009) used the same dataset as Kempf and Osthoff (2007) and found that stocks with high social responsibility ratings performed generally better than stocks with low social responsibility ratings. However, none of the results were statistically significant except for the employee screen. Hong and Kacperczyk (2009) studied the performance of sin stocks on the American market over the period 1965-2003. They found that sin stocks perform better than non-sin stocks in their sample. However, the difference in return is not statistically significant. Biehl, Dumke, Hoepner, and Wilson (2010) consider UK SRI funds and show that the portfolios with the highest social ratings underperform significantly, while the portfolios with the lowest social ratings do not significantly underperform the market. Charlo Molina and Moya Clemente (2010) analyze financial performance of Spanish SR companies and they highlighted that stocks of companies that are SR earn returns on excess over systematic risk, making them investment-attractive and they have a higher systematic risk. Basso and Funari (2014) evaluate the performance of European SRI funds relying on data envelopment analysis (DEA). Their empirical study suggests that it is possible to invest in a socially responsible manner without having to renounce financial reward. Miralles Marcelo, Miralles Quiros, and Miralles Quiros (2012) analyze the return performance of sustainable firms quoted on the Spanish stock market over the 2001-2010 period and they compare risk exposure for sustainable and conventional firms. They indicate that investing in SR companies provides a risk adjusted return negative. However, they also note that in economic crisis SR investment turns out to be safer. Finally, Capelle-Blancard and Monjon (2014) measure the financial performance of a sample of 116 French SRI mutual funds over the period 2004-2007. They results show that SRI funds do not outperform the market, whatever the performance measure considered.

Recently, several studies (see for example, Humphrey & Lee, 2011; Lee, Humphrey, Benson, &Ahn, 2010; Renneboog, TerHorst, & Zhang, 2008b; Renneboog, Ter Horst, & Zhang, 2011) have proposed not to compare the performance of SRI funds with those of conventional funds, but to consider the relative performance between SRI funds. By doing this, they provide an in-depth analysis of the relationship between the selection process of SRI funds and their financial performances. The findings of these studies show there is a relationship between the screening intensity and SRI financial performance. In general, depending on parameters such as product category, time period, geographical market, benchmark and performance measure, studies may conclude different results

about SRI. In addition, SRI is not a standard concept (Sandberg, Juravle, Hedesstrom, & Hamilton, 2009).

Quantitative modelisation of the goals of a SR investor is complicated and nowadays it is an open problem. In this sense, Hallerbach, Ning, Soppe, and Spronk (2004) have considered the difficulty of measuring the degree of SR of individual investments, given that a welfare function which includes all social aspects is not available. On the other hand, the UK Social Investment Forum website (UKSIF) indicates that though the majority of people agree with what are the ethical issues, each individual must decide if a specific investment meets her criteria: "different people have different views as to what is acceptable and how important a set issue is for them". However, the UKSIF identifies what characterizes good SRI: "What they have in common is that they clearly state views on SEE issues. The key is to deliver and use information on the investments in such a way that those who invest may decide whether such investments are suitable for their clients and their pension funds" (UK Social Investment Forum, http://www.uksif.org/). Therefore, the design of SR portfolios requires information about the compliance with SR criteria by companies and investment fund management. Also, it is necessary information about individual or collective perception as to what is ethical or profitable for the Society (Cabello, Ruiz, Pérez-Gladish, & Méndez-Rodríguez, 2014). Both inputs have imprecision and so our proposal is to construct an objective that measures the SR Quality of a portfolio based on linguistic labels and a quantitative treatment using fuzzy aggregation operators.

The variety of financial instruments and opportunities for the SR investors are increasing constantly; SR funds are collective investment institutions whose object is to channel savings toward those companies or organizations which, in agreement with the ethical report of the fund, meet the criteria therein reflected. These financial products make up, currently, the main instrument of socially responsible investment.

The model we propose in this paper allows us to obtain a portfolio made up of SR funds which replicates or tracks the portfolio that an investor would have chosen if she did not take into account SEE considerations in her investment decisions. Because the financial sacrifice, as a consequence of limiting the financial assets to those that have been qualified as SR, is a major concern of this particular investment market, we consider it should be useful to have a tool that evaluates this possible financial loss and tries to minimize it, for the increasing demand by investors that make their investment decisions based on their ethical principles.

Several works close to ours are commented below. A pioneering research is carried out by Hallerbach et al. (2004) which give a practical approach for portfolio selection utilizing multi-attributive preference functions. Bilbao-Terol, Arenas-Parra, Cañal-Fernández, and Bilbao-Terol (2013) use the Hedonic Price Method in order to obtain an evaluation of SRI criteria that is integrated into a multi-objective mathematical programming model. Ballestero, Bravo, Perez-Gladish, Arenas-Parra, and Pla-Santamaria (2012) provide a financial-ethical bi-criteria model especially for SRI portfolio selection. Furthermore, studies like Abdelaziz, Aouni, and el Fayedh (2007) and Steuer, Qi, and Hirschberger (2007) argue that portfolio selection is a multi-objective problem. All of the mentioned papers also use multi-criteria methodologies like us but with different aims to that of the present work.

Drut (2010a) investigates the penalty for responsible investing. Social ratings are introduced in mean-variance optimization through linear constraints to explore the implications of considering a social responsibility (SR) threshold in the traditional Markowitz (1952) portfolio selection setting. Therefore, there are two main differences with our work: the portfolio minimizing the distance to its conventional peer is not searched and the SR Quality of the portfolio is not taking into account as an objective through the selection process. Dorfleitner and Utz (2012), expand the

■CSMI PUW^^B AIIIIILE IN PRESS

4 A. Bilbao-Terol etal./ Revista de Contabilidad - Spanish Accounting Review xxx (xx) (2015) xxx-xxx

methodological spectrum of socially responsible investing. They introduce stochastic sustainability returns into safety first models (introduced by Roy, 1952) for portfolio choice. They propose as objective function a convex linear combination of the expected financial return and the expected social return and constraints of probability for controlling the risk. Therefore, Dorfleitner and Utz proposal shares with the current paper the use of downside risk measures and the inclusion of a sustainability objective into the modeling. However, our sustainability returns are fuzzy, i.e. have imprecision no probabilistic, instead of stochastic one, and beside their model does not look for minimizing the financial loss.

Our model runs in two stages. In the first one it is necessary to obtain the reference portfolio, made up exclusively of conventional funds. For the construction of the conventional portfolio the Prospect Theory (Kahneman & Tversky, 1979) has been used (net profits as the financial objective and error function as the utility function). We use an approach in two steps: calculate the efficient frontier with respect to two criteria, the expected value at the end (EVE) and the CVaR. On this efficient frontier we obtain the most preferred portfolio by the investor using the certainty-equivalent in the case of the error function utility.

In the second stage a portfolio is obtained made up exclusively by SR funds using the reference portfolio from the first stage as a level of aspiration or ideal point with respect to the financial performance of the preferred SR portfolio.

As a consequence the investor will have objectives as the relative wealth with respect to the reference portfolio and the SR-value of the portfolio. The relative wealth will be manipulated by means of its CVaR and the periodic values of the portfolio. The second objective is constructed in agreement with the social, environmental and ethical preferences of the investor. For this point we have used the Fuzzy Set Theory (Zadeh, 1965) to treat the imprecise assessments of the investor with respect to her preferences, motivations and/or social concerns. Bellman and Zadeh (1970) set the basic principles of decision making in fuzzy environments. When constructing a portfolio where ethical features are addressed, two problems arise: to represent uncertain knowledge about a certain parameter, and to represent a degree of satisfaction for the investor with regard to his/her social preference structure. Both problems have been handled by Fuzzy Decision Making in Multiobjective Programming models (see Bilbao, Arenas, Rodríguez, & Antomil, 2007; Bilbao-Terol, Arenas-Parra, & Canal-Fernández, 2012; Gupta, Mehlawat, & Saxena, 2008; Huang, 2007; Kaya & Kahramana, 2010; Merigó & Gil-Fuente, 2010; Wu & Tsai, 2014; Zhang, Wang, Chen, & Nie, 2007).

There are many economic problems such as the selection of portfolios, where the choice of the best decision should be made taking into account several criteria. Multi-objective programming is a mathematical technique used to solve these types ofproblems. This approach involves acknowledging that the decision maker is responding to multiple objectives. Generally, objectives are conflicting; therefore, not all objectives can simultaneously reach their optimal values. Zopounidis and Doumpos (2013) present a detailed discussion and up-to-date review on two important areas of financial decision support, namely portfolio selection and corporate performance evaluation. Besides, they are also given to highlight how different multicriteria modeling approaches complement and enhance existing techniques from the areas of finance and operations research. There are a broad range of multi-objective methods such as Weighted Programming, Constraint Programming, Compromise Programming, Composite Programming, Reference Point Method and Goal Programming (GP). The latest was first introduced by Charnes, Cooper, and Ferguson (1955) and Charnes and Cooper (1961). Over the years, the GP model has become the most widely used approach in the field of multiple criteria decision making, particularly for portfolio selection problem. The major advantage of the

GP is its inherent flexibility in handling decision-making problems with numerous conflicting objectives and incomplete or imprecise information (Caballero, Luque, Jolina, & Ruiz, 2005; Caballero, Gómez, & Ruiz, 2009; Chang, 2007; Romero, 1991,2004). A detailed analysis of GP models and their applications can be found in the book of Jones and Tamiz (2010). Many decision makers prefer to seek solutions that are "good enough" or "close enough" rather than optimal. GP allows multiple objectives to be handled under a "satisficing philosophy", developed by Simon (1956), expressed by means of the concept of goal. Designing a GP model involves the Decision Maker sets "aspiration levels" a priori for the objectives of his decision. Such targets, together with the objectives, constitute the "goals" of the problem. The pioneering applications of GP for portfolio selection are due to Lee and Lerro (1973). More recently, many other applications in this field have appeared in the literature (Abdelaziz et al., 2007; Arenas Parra, Bilbao Terol, & Rodriguez Uría, 2001; Bilbao et al., 2007; Hsin-Hung, 2008; Kaminski et al., 2009; Trenado, Romero, Cuadrado, & Romero, 2014). For an updated literature review on application of GP models to financial portfolio management from the 1970s to nowadays see Aouni, Colapino, and La Torre (2014).

In the last stage of our modeling process, a multi-objective model associated to the SR portfolio selection arises. Its objectives are the CVaR concerning to the relative loss with respect to the reference portfolio, the values of the portfolio on each scenario and the SR Quality of the portfolio. This multi-objective model is tackled by using the Goal Programming methodology. We have implemented the model using as a market 38 conventional and 12 SR investment funds domiciled in Spain. We have worked with the weekly price data from March 10, 2006 to December 31, 2009.

This paper is organized as follows. After this introduction, in Section 2 a brief review of the Copula Theory is presented. Section 3 is devoted to the constructing of the reference portfolio. From this, the following section shows the SR-portfolio selection process including the modeling of the SR-objective. Results are shown in Section 5 and the conclusions finish this paper.

2. Copula Theory

Empirical studies find that the assumption of normality of financial returns distribution is not hold. The non-normality has been examined using the skewness and the kurtosis. Some studies obtain evidence of negative skewness and excess kurtosis. Specifically, negative skewness indicates a higher probability of negative returns, that is, the market gives higher probability to decreases than increases in asset pricing while excess kurtosis makes extreme observations more likely than in the normal case, which means that the market gives higher probability to extreme observations than in normal distribution. Consequently, the linear correlation coefficient is no longer suitable and can largely lead to misleading results (Boubaker &Sghaier, 2013; Embrechts, McNeil, & Straumann, 1999; Embrechts, McNeil, & Straumann, 2002; Forbes & Rigobon, 2000). Furthermore, several researchers find evidence of asymmetry in the dependence between stock market returns (Ang & Bekaert, 2002; Ang & Chen, 2002; Das & Uppal, 2004; Hong, Tu, & Zhou, 2007; Patton, 2004) and between exchange rate returns (Beine, 2004; Li, 2011). In particular, stock market returns exhibit greater dependence during market downturns than market upturns and exchange rate returns seem to be more correlated in periods of depreciation that in periods of appreciation which increase the downside risk.

In order to reproduce the asymmetric dependence between financial returns, some studies propose to work with the concept of exceedance correlation (Ang & Chen, 2002) and the extreme value theory (Beine, Cosma, & Vermeulen, 2010; Hartmann, Straeman,

'"I'WW^M AIIIIII .E IN PRESS

A. Bilbao-Terol et al./ Revista de Contabilidad - Spanish Accounting Review xxx (xx) (2015) xxx-xxx

& de Vries, 2004; Poon, Rockinger, & Tawn, 2004). A drawback of these methods, is that they are subject to the trouble of choosing the appropriate threshold and the use of the extreme value distribution such as Pareto distribution.

Other authors consider multivariate Generalized AutoRegressive Conditional Heteroskedasticity (GARCH) model with skewness (Harvey & Siddique, 1999) and/or kurtosis (Jondeau & Rockinger, 2003; Brooks, Burke, Heravi, & Persand, 2005). Also, several researches are based on regime-switching models (Ang & Bekaert, 2002; Ang & Chen, 2002). Although these models allow for time-varying conditional correlations, they cannot reproduce asymmetries in asymptotic tail dependence (Boubaker & Sghaier, 2013).

For the above reasons we use a semi-parametric approach based on a statistical tool: Copula Theory now being applied in Finance and Insurance (see, for example Boubaker & Sghaier, 2013; Bouyé, Durrleman, Nikeghbali, Riboulet & Roncalli, 2001; Cherubini et al., 2004; Cintas del Río, 2007; Dias & Embrechts, 2004; Embrechts, Lindskog, & McNeil, 2001; Keel, 2006; Meucci, 2006; Rank, 2002; Rivas & Cuesta, 2006; Romano, 2002) in order to carry out the market estimation. Nelsen (1999) is a standard reference on the subject of copulas. In this paper, we model multivariate distribution of invariants - in our market these are the weekly log returns on the funds - by means of a very general specification: each of the invariants is fitted independently of the different univariate distributions and the dependence of these invariants is modeled in terms of a multivariate copula.

The copulas are a suitable instrument with which to represent dependence relations among random variables across ajoint probability distribution. In fact, the joint cumulative distribution function of random variables can be expressed as a copula function applied to the marginal distributions of each one of them. If the marginal distributions are continuous the copula is unique. This result known as Sklar's theorem (Sklar, 1959) is the most important one in the Copula Theory with a broad practical application given that it provides a tool for generating multivariate distributions with marginal distributions fixed in a way that the marginal univariate functions can have a separate structure from the structure of the copula.

Essentially, a copula is a multivariate distribution function defined over the hyper-cube unit with the marginals distributed uniformly.

2.1. Definition of copula

A copula n-dimensional is a function C with the following properties:

C : [0,1]n ^ [0,1]

C(u(i)) = u, u(i) = (1, ..., u..., 1) C(u) = 0 if u = (u1,...,un) Su, = 0

^ (1) 2^(-1)2_j'C(U1 + J1A1, ..., Un + jnAn) >0

j=0 i=1

0 < Uk + jkAk <1 j = Y)i2' ji = 0, 11

From this definition, if F1.....Fn are continuous univariate distribution functions then

2.2. Sklar's theorem

Let F be an n-dimensional distribution function with the

marginals F1(x1).....Fn(xn) then there exists a copula C such

that C(u) = F(F-1(u1), . ..,F-1(u n)). Furthermore, if C is an n-dimensional copula it is verified F(x) = C(Fi(xi).....Fn(un)).

Copula functions are important because they allow to decouple statistical inference into two parts: inference of the marginals and inference of the dependence. The modeling process in the copula framework has, therefore, two levels, one relative to the modeling of the marginals and the other relative to the modeling of the dependence of such marginals, that is, to choose the appropriate copula. For both levels it is possible to use parametric or nonpara-metric models.

In this paper we use the Student t copula (t-copula), a class of elliptic copula, widely accepted in financial literature; there are other types of copulas used in Finance and Insurance such as Archimedean copulas, extreme value copulas or Marshall-Okin copulas, which we have not considered here.

Elliptic distributions play an important role in Finance due to the fact that they constitute a source of multivariate distributions that have many of the good properties of multivariate normal distributions and facilitate obtaining multivariate models for extremes and other forms of non-normal dependency. Elliptic copulas are simply the copulas of elliptic distributions. Simulation using these type of distributions is simple and, as a consequence of Sklar's theorem so it is too with elliptic copulas. Furthermore, they allow to easily calculate range correlation and tail dependence coefficients. The concept of tail dependence describes the dependence of extreme values. In an approximate way, tail dependence is the probability of having a high (low) extreme value for Y given that one has a high (low) extreme value for X. We differentiate between superior and inferior tail dependence. For elliptic distributions, these two measurements are the same. In Finance, what is of interest is, above all, inferior tail dependence since it implies extreme concurrent losses.

According to the above mentioned, the t-copula corresponds to the distribution of the same name. Therefore, the multivariate t-copula is defined by:

cV,R(ui , . . .UN) = t„,R(t„ 1 (Ui ), t- 1(UN))

F (x) = C(Fi(xi ),..., Fn(un ))

is a multivariate distribution function with the marginals distributed uniformly because u = Fj(Xj) is a uniform random variable.

where tv,R is the standardized Student t distribution with v degrees of freedom and shape matrix R, and tv denotes the standardized univariate Student t distribution with v degrees of freedom, that is, the margins of tv R.

Demarta and McNeil (2005) study the properties of this copula and others related to it. Furthermore, Malevergne and Sornette (2003) and Dias and Embrechts (2004) obtain good results for this class of copula in comparison to the Archimedean. Romano (2002) proves that the use of a copula function different to the Gaussian captures extreme events more effectively. He studied a portfolio of 10 Italian shares using a t-copula, which improved the results of a normal copula in the estimation of risk measurement. Rank (2002) and Keel (2006), among others, obtained similar results on the use of the t-copula.

The performance of t-copulas utilized in this paper, both for modeling the conventional and the SR market, will be shown in the two following sections.

3. Obtaining the reference portfolio

The aim is to find the portfolio with the financial characteristics desired by the SR investor when she neglects her SR concerns and behaves like a conventional investor.

МНИИ^^И IIIII.E IN PRESS

A. Bilbao-Terol et al./ Revista de Contabilidad - Spanish Accounting Review xxx (xx) (2015) xxx-xxx

3.1. The market

Our market is made up of 38 conventional Spanish investment funds, therefore, N =38. We have weekly data of prices from March 10, 2006 to December 31, 2009. In total we have 995 observations. We have set an estimation interval of 1 week (5 days of trading) and a starting point from 3 years and 9 months and 20 days, the moment of investment is T =198. The investment horizon for the specific investor, h, has been set at one month (4 weeks). The names of the funds and their investment policy (according to memo 1/2009 of Feb 4 of the National Securities Market Commission, CNMV) i.e. the regulatory body of the Spanish Stock Market on the categories of collective investment institutions according to their investment policy) appear in Tables A1 and A2 of the Appendix.

3.1.1. Estimation of the market invariants

As market invariants we have chosen the non-overlapping weekly log returns on the funds:

rit = ln(Pp+i) , t = 1, 2,..., 198, i = 1, 2,..., 38 (4)

being Pit the price of the fund i in the week t. In order to test the hypothesis of stationary a graphical test (see Fig. 1) and also the KPSS test (Kwiatkowski, Phillips, Schmidt, & Shin, 1992) have been applied. The KPS statistics for 37 funds are less than its critical value (0.347 for significance at the 10 percent); therefore, it is not possible to reject the hypothesis of stationarity at 10% for all series least one and for the series with a statistic value greater than 0.347 it is not possible to reject the hypothesis at 1%.

We have chosen log returns instead of total returns or linear ones for two reasons. Firstly, combined returns are easy to project on any investment horizon unlike total and linear ones (Meucci, 2007).

Secondly, distribution of both total returns and linear ones will not be symmetric. However, distribution of log returns is approximately symmetric. Also it is possible to model the joint distribution of the log returns of a set of funds by means of a distribution of elliptic type.

In this paper we model the marginal distributions of weekly log returns by means of a nonparametric approach using the empirical distribution smoothed by means of a Gaussian kernel. The modeling of the dependence structure is carried out by means of a t-copula applying the method of maximum likelihood in order to determine its parameters.

3.1.2. Estimating the marginals: smoothing with Gaussian kernel

The main advantage of the empirical marginal distribution is that it is calculated easily for any real x from the sample {x1,... xT} :

Ft (x) = 1^/(-OT,x](Xi) (5)

being I the usual indicator function.

The main deficiency of the empirical marginal distributions is that the tails might not reflect the true tails of the underlying distribution.

It is possible to remedy this problem using kernel estimators for the densities:

FT (x) = 1E H^) (6)

-G.G1 -G.GG5 G G.GG5 G.G1 -G.G1 -G.GG5 G G.GG5 G.G1

ЧРИ^^И ARIIILE IN PRESS

A. Bilbao-Terol et al./ Revista de Contabilidad - Spanish Accounting Review xxx (xx) (2015) xxx-xxx

Skewness=-0.4762 Kurtosis=4.9922

- .-Ill

-0.15 -0.1 -0.05 0 X

G.G5 G.1 G.15

-2-1 0 12 Standard normal quantiles

Fig. 2. Histogram for Banif Estructurado FI.

Fig. 4. Log returns for Banif Estructurado FI.

-0.2 -0.15 -0.1 -0.05 0 0.05 0.1 0.

Fig. З. Kernel density for BanifEstructurado FI.

Column number Fig. 5. Box-plot for Banif Estructurado FI.

Being K the Gaussian kernel3 and e the bandwidth. Following the conditions of Silverman (1986), the latter can be taken following an automatic criterion of the type: e = 0.9T-1/5min(R/1.34, s), R and s being, respectively, the sample interquartile range and the sample standard deviation. Alternatively, the bandwidth can be found by using the least square cross-section validation. In this work we have used Gaussian kernel estimators for the marginal densities with automatic bandwidth.

In Figs. 2-5 a graphic description is shown of the weekly log returns of the first fund (Banif Estructurado FI) of our database. The histogram reflects a leptokurtic distribution (observe, also the kernel density adjusted in the bottom image); and the corresponding box-plot presents a series of high frequency in tails, which coincides with the information provided by the QQ plot that sets the empirical quantiles against those of a normal one, in which can be appreciated both the more fat tails of the empirical distribution than those which correspond to a normal distribution. Similar characteristics can be appreciated in the rest of the funds.

The numerical characteristics corresponding to each series of weekly log returns appear in Tables A1 and A2 in the Appendix, where Q¡ represents the ith quartile of the invariant distribution.

3.1.3. Modeling the dependence structure: Student t copulas

As we have said, the modeling process in the copula framework has two levels, one relative to the modeling of the marginals and the other relative to the copula function linking such marginals. The modeling of the dependence structure of the univariate distributions is carried out by means of a t-copula applying the method of maximum likelihood (ML) in order to determine the parameters of the same. A summary of the results obtained follows (Table 1).

The low number of freedom degrees shows high tail dependence (Keel, 2006; Meucci, 2006). In summary, the estimations of the invariants, on the two levels, have been carried out according to:

1) The marginal distributions by using Gaussian kernel densities. Also we find the quantiles of the smoothed marginals: Qs(u) = Fs-1(u) = inf{x/Fs(x) < u} where Fs is the smoothed distribution function of the marginal s.

2) The t-copula for the dependence structure.

Table 1

Results of the t-copula fitting using ML.

3 ВД = Tbe-x2/2.

Degrees of freedom 7.4

Minimum negative loglikelihood -9408

Akaike Information Criterion (AIC) -18,662

■CSMIPUW^^B IIIILE IN PRESS

A. Bilbao-Terol et al./ Revista de Contabilidad - Spanish Accounting Review xxx (xx) (2015) xxx-xxx

-0.2 -0.15 -0.1 -0.05 0 X

0.05 0.1

Fig. 6. The smoothed, simulated and historical distributions of Banif Estructurado FI.

We are now able to simulate the joint distribution of the weekly log returns of the funds in the following way in the following way:

• Simulate a random sample of the t-copula determined on Step 2: tSample with size equals to J =5000 scenarios.

• Apply the sample values into copula: Ft-Student(tSample) = U =(U1, ..., UN).

• Apply the quantiles, Qs, of the marginals into U: Qs(Us), then, the joint distribution of Qs(Us) follows the same distribution than the original data.

In Fig. 6 the smoothed, simulated and historical distributions appear for the first fund of the database. In this, one can appreciate the goodness of the fit. We have also applied the K-S test to the simulated and historical distributions. The result obtained allows us not to reject the hypothesis that the simulated and historical distributions come from the same distribution at a 95% confidence level. We have graphed the corresponding QQplot to compare the quantiles of the distributions (Fig. 7).

Before going into the calculation of the reference portfolio, it is necessary to apply the distributions of the invariants to the fund prices. This involves, firstly, projecting the invariants onto the investment horizon (applying the square root rule). In our case, the projection factor is equal to four given that we pass from a

-0.15 -0.1

-0.05 0

X quantiles

Fig. 7. QQplot historical and simulated of Banif Estructurado FI.

Fig. 8. The value function.

Source: Kahneman (2002).

weekly estimation horizon to a monthly investment horizon. Based on simulated weekly log returns, rit, it is possible to get a simulation

of the fund prices according to the relation: Pj = PiTe^i=irit, j =

1, ...,J.

3.2. Portfolio optimality

In this paper maximization of net profits (the difference between the final value of the portfolio and the amount invested) has been set as the financial objective of the investor. This objective is a consequence of the descriptive theory on decision making - Prospect Theory - developed by Kahneman and Tversky (1979).

In their theory they expressly emphasize that "ordinary people" have a structured perceptive model in order to recognize changes and differences rather than to appreciate absolute dimensions. Kahneman and Tversky point out that value is given as a result of the changes in economic states and not through states themselves. The experimental studies carried out by them allow us to conclude that individuals are adverse to risk when they are in situations of gain but, however, seek risk when they are in situations of loss (Kahneman, 2000; Kahneman, Knetsch, & Thaler, 1990; Tversky & Kahneman, 1992).

This is observed in the classic S-shaped graph (Fig. 8) set out by the authors. It shows that to earn 200 monetary units produces a pleasure, a utility of 25 units. If one looks at the lower lefthand quadrant one sees that to lose 200 monetary units produces a negative disutility of more than 50 units.

Prospect Theory (Fung, 2006; Mason, Jason Shogren, & List, 2005; Nevins, 2004; Ricciardi, 2008; Shiller & Thaler, 2007; Shiller, 2006; Wakker, Timmermans, & Machielse, 2007) is empirically based and aspires to reflect how people behave in reality, not how they ought to behave if they were rational. It is not, then, a normative theory but empirical and positive. Its essential differences with respect to the Expected Utility Theory refer to three important questions: the definition of the alternatives upon which are human decisions are based; the value we give them; and the weighting we attribute to them in the light of their probability. Prospect Theory assumes that limited human intellectual capacity

ЧРИ^^И ARIIILE IN PRESS

A. Bilbao-Terol et al./ Revista de Contabilidad - Spanish Accounting Review xxx (xx) (2015) xxx-xxx

obliges us "to edit" or simplify the problems of decision-making that we are confronted with and we do this by following certain heuristic rules. The first and most important one is that when we judge alternatives we do not compare absolute values (this is the assumption of the Expected Utility Theory) but variations or changes with respect to a certain level that we take as a reference point. Thus, alternatives are assessed in terms of gains or losses with respect to a certain level of reference. This level of reference is usually that of the status quo but it might be a psychological level to which we aspire or even an arbitrary one. This behavior is, therefore, the basis for using net profits as the investor's objective.

The net profits random variable is represented on the real number line by means of the expected value at the end EVE and the CVaR associated with net profits at a certain confidence level, a.

In order to select the optimum portfolio under both criteria we proceed in two steps:

1. Obtain an approximation of the efficient frontier CVaR-EVE.

2. On the efficient frontier calculate the portfolio with maximum certainty-equivalent with utility associated with the objective of net profits. In order to do this an error function is used with an S-shaped according to that prescribed in Prospect Theory.

3.3. Calculating the reference portfolio

Let P = (P1.....PN) be the random vector of the prices of the financial instruments N at the end of the investment period T + h; x = (x1, ...,xN) the portfolio to determine beingxi the shares invested in the instrument i and C0 the initial available capital. The net loss variable for the period is the difference between the initial value and the final value of the portfolio: L(x, P; Co) = Co -P'x.

We have simulated J scenarios for the fund prices according to that set out above. By Pj we denote the price of the fund i in the scenario j and we suppose that the scenarios are equally probable. The minimization of the CVaR is carried out following the model proposed by Rockafellar and Uryasev (2000). Next we shall set out the algorithm to be applied and the results obtained.

Step 1. Approximate the efficient frontier CVaR-EVE.

Firstly, we calculate the EVE of the portfolio with minimum CVaRa solving the following linear problem:

min ? ± ïïrbîÊz

J(1 -а)^ ~>

Zj > ^(-PijXi) ± CQ - ? i=1

5>X = CQ

Zj > 0, Xj > 0

The efficient frontier is generated by solving the collection of problems where the CVaRa is minimized subject to the constraints that the EVE is greater than or equal to the values equally spaced between the EVE corresponding to the minimum CVaRa portfolio and the EVE obtained with the portfolio composed by the fund which has the greatest expected price per monetary unit invested, that is to say, we apply the e-constraint method, proposed by

Table 2

The efficient values CVaR and EVE (conventional funds).

Portfolio CVaR EVE Portfolio CVaR EVE

1 0.9703 100.2124 21 12.2165 101.1426

2 1.0975 100.2589 22 12.8479 101.1892

3 1.4193 100.3054 23 13.4793 101.2357

4 1.8826 100.3519 24 14.1108 101.2822

5 2.4079 100.3984 25 14.7424 101.3287

6 2.9625 100.4449 26 15.3742 101.3752

7 3.5398 100.4915 27 16.0063 101.4217

8 4.1356 100.538 28 16.639 101.4682

9 4.7368 100.5845 29 17.2719 101.5147

10 5.345 100.631 30 17.9049 101.5613

11 5.9585 100.6775 31 18.5381 101.6078

12 6.5758 100.724 32 19.1714 101.6543

13 7.1956 100.7705 33 19.8046 101.7008

14 7.8182 100.817 34 20.4379 101.7473

15 8.4428 100.8636 35 21.072 101.7938

16 9.0693 100.9101 36 21.7075 101.8403

17 9.6965 100.9566 37 22.3438 101.8869

18 10.3252 101.0031 38 22.9822 101.9334

19 10.9547 101.0496 39 23.7095 101.9799

20 11.5851 101.0961 40 24.6455 102.0264

Haimes, Lasdon, and Wismer (1971), to the following bi-objective problem:

min CVaRa(x)

cEVE(x) = ^ E[pí ]X

5>X = C0

Zj > 0, Xj > 0

where E[P, ] is the price of the i asset. The solution for problem (8) allows us to obtain the efficient frontier (see Table 2).

Step 2. Obtain the maximum certainty-equivalent portfolio on the efficient frontier. The investor's objective is the difference between the final value of the portfolio and the amount invested (net profits):

f (X) = VT±h(x) - Cq

We use the error function to model the investor's utility - with S-shaped according to Prospect Theory (Kahneman & Tversky, 1979) - being ^ a positive parameter which we have set equal to 0.5 (Meucci, 2007):

u(f (x)) = er

where er(x) = J^ e "2du. The domain of er(x) is the whole real axis; therefore, this function describes the attitude toward risk in the case of gains: positive values of the objective and in the case of losses, i.e., negative values of the objective. The expression for the Arrow-Pratt's coefficient of risk aversion corresponding to the error function reads:

A(f (x)) = f(X)

therefore, assuming ^ >0, when the investor faces net gains, i.e. f(x)>0, the Arrow-Pratt's coefficient is positive and thus the investor is risk averse. On the contrary, if the objective is negative, i.e. there is a net losses situation, then, the Arrow-Pratt's coefficient is negative, so, the investor is risk prone and is willing to pay a premium to invest in risky assets.

■CSMiWT^^B iiiile in press

10 A. Bilbao-Terol et al. / Revista de Contabilidad -

Table 3

Composition and characteristics of the reference portfolio.

Composition:

BBK Renta Global FI 90.7152 €

BBVA Bolsa Asia MF FI 1.8498 €

Beta Alpha Dinámico FI 4.6692 €

AC Inversión Selectiva FI 2.7659 €

Characteristics:

EVE 100.3054

CVaR 1.4193

VaR 0.9481

Performance (EVE/CVaR) 70.6724

5th percentile values of the distribution = 99.0519 = 100 - VaR. Frequency of portfolio under 100 - VaR = 249/5000 = 0.0498 <1 -a.

Spanish Accounting Review xxx (xx) (2015) xxx-xxx

4. Obtaining the socially responsible portfolio

In the second stage a portfolio is obtained made up exclusively by SR funds using the reference portfolio from the first stage as a level of aspiration or ideal point with respect to the financial performance of the preferred SR portfolio.

As a consequence the investor will have as objectives the relative wealth with respect to the reference portfolio and the SR-value of the portfolio. The relative wealth will be manipulated by means of its CVaR and the periodic values of the portfolio. The second objective is constructed in agreement with the social, environmental and ethical preferences of the investor.

4.1. The market

We calculate the utility of each efficient portfolio using sample prices of the funds - according to what we have set out in the previous section- and from this, its certainty-equivalent (CE), that is, the risk-free amount of money that would make the investor as satisfied as the risky portfolio. The CE is calculated as the inverse of the utility on the expected utility. In our case the CE reads:

CE(x) = er-1(0)v/2^ (12)

where 0 is the expected utility (the average of utilities).

The maximum CE on efficient portfolios determines the reference portfolio x*, which in this case study turns out to be the efficient portfolio number 3, whose composition and characteristics are included in Table 3:

Therefore, the probability that the monetary value of the portfolio is less than 99.0519 is less than 0.05 and the EVE of the portfolio conditional on the value is less than 100-VaR is equal to 98.5789. Fig. 9 shows the results of the steps that allow us to determine the reference portfolio.

In this stage the market is composed of 12 socially responsible funds together with the reference portfolio constructed previously. The historical series go from the period already indicated (March 10, 2006 to December 31, 2009) and have been dealt with in the same way as in the previous stage; therefore here also we have worked with weekly log returns which we have checked to be market invariants (the KPSS statistics for all funds are less than its critical value, 0.347, for significance at the 10 percent).

The study of our SR mutual funds database shows the sharp drop in the last quarter of 2008 (coinciding with the global financial crisis) and early 2009. However, the subsequent behavior of the funds is unalike; for example, some of them have recovered dramatically better as in the case of Santander Responsabilidad Coservd FI or Caixa Catalunya Europa Valor FI, at the same time that others such as Gesbeta Compromiso Fondo Ético FI or Foncaixa Coop. Soc. Resp. Europa FI have failed to recover their previous levels.

The graphs of the time series of funds and dates where the minimum and maximum prices occurred have been included in the Appendix (Figs. A1-A12 and Table A3).

10 1 CVaR

Fig. 9. Reference portfolio.

ЧРИ^^И ARTICLE IN PRESS

A. Bilbao-Terol etal./ Revista de Contabilidad - Spanish Accounting Review xxx (xx) (2015) xxx-xxx 11

Table 4

The numerical characteristics to each series of weekly log returns.

Fund Type of fund Q1 Q22 Q3 Mean Skewness Kurtosis

AC Responsable 30 FI RFMI -0.0039 0.0001 0.003 -0.0005 -0.4072 5.2037

BBK Solidaria FI RFM -0.003В 0.0007 0.0045 0.0005 -0.1514 3.9275

BBVA Bolsa Desarrollo Sostenible FI RVIO -0.0163 0.0001 0.013В -0.0006 0.2202 5.3602

BNP Paribas Fondo Solidaridad FI RVIE -0.0043 0.001 0.0046 0 -0.2622 3.В772

Caixa Catalunya Europa Valor FI RVMI -0.0197 0 0.01В4 -0.0012 -0.1В22 5.4193

Foncaixa Coop. Soc. Resp. Europa FI RVIE -0.0177 0.001 0.0161 -0.000В 0.0В5В 6.623В

Foncaixa Priv. Fondo Act. Ético FI RVMI -0.0041 0.0005 0.0057 0.000В 0.2405 4.216

Fondo Solidario ProUnicef FI RFMI -0.0031 0.0006 0.004В 0.0004 -0.237 4.4397

Gesbeta Compromiso Fondo Ético FI FGL -0.0035 0.001 0.0036 -0.0002 -0.5722 5.1245

Inveractivo Confianza FI FGL -0.0014 0.0006 0.0021 0.0002 -0.В229 5.6206

Santander Dividendo Solidario FI RVIE -0.0132 0.0015 0.0156 0.0001 -0.3343 5.9411

Santander Responsabilidad Coservd FI RFM -0.0015 0.0005 0.0026 0.0005 0.0724 3.964В

70 SO SO 40 30 2O 10 O

-0.03 -0.02

Fig. 10. Histogram and kernel density of AC Responsable 30 FI.

4.1.1. Estimation of the market invariants

In order to carry out this task we follow the same steps as those already commented upon in stage 1, that is, we apply the t-copula fitting where the marginal distributions are modeled as Gaussian kernel smoothed distributions. We have made a study of the marginals parallel to that done for the case of conventional funds.

For the first SR fund, the histogram (Fig. 10) reflects a leptokur-tic distribution and the corresponding box-plot presents a series of high frequency in tails, which coincides with the information showed in the QQ-plot (Fig. 11), a plot of the quantiles of the empirical distribution against those of a normal one, in which the tails of our empirical distribution are fatter than the tails of the normal distribution. Similar characteristics can be appreciated for the rest of the funds.

The numerical characteristics corresponding to each series of weekly log returns appear in Table 4, where Q represents the ith quartile of the distribution of the invariant.

In the second level of the invariant modeling, the copula has been obtained (Table 5). Again, the low number of degrees of freedom of the t-copula shows high tail dependence.

Table 5

Results of the t-copula fitting using ML.

4.2. Optimality of the SR portfolio

4.2.1. Financial objective

Given that we are attempting "to track" the reference portfolio, the financial objective of the investor is the relative wealth with respect to this portfolio. Therefore the objective is the difference between the value at the end of the investment horizon of the SR portfolio, x, made up exclusively of SR funds and the value of the reference portfolio, x*. As surrogates on the real line of this random objective we consider:

the CVaR concerning the relative loss with respect to the reference portfolio:

min f + T7T-— J(1 -

J(1 - a) -

zj > 0, x,- > g

0.03 O.O2 0.01 0

-0.01 -0.02

QQ plot AC responsable 30 FI

-0.03 -3

a^t_________________

* ++ +

-10 12 Box-plot AC responsable 30 FI

Degrees of freedom 6.9В4

Minimum negative loglikelihood -1В73 Fig. 11

Column number

МИИ^^И ARIIILE IN PRESS

A. Bilbao-Terol et al./ Revista de Contabilidad - Spanish Accounting Review xxx (xx) (2015) xxx-xxx

the values of the relative wealth on each scenario:

>0, j = 1,...,J

i=1 keCF

4.2.2. Ethical objective

Aside from the financial objective, substituted by its real surrogates, we have considered an objective relative to the ethical quality of the portfolio in relation to the interests of the investor. We have tackled the treatment of this objective from a subjective perspective for a specific investor.

The methodology used has been Fuzzy Logic. Thus we propose to evaluate the ethical quality of an investment fund by means of an indicator we have called SR Quality and which evaluates in a aggregated way, while attending the preferences of the investor, the SR characteristics of investment funds. According to Barracchini (2007), the SR Quality of each fund is a subjective measure, referring to the qualitative characteristics of the fund and whose value is referred to the ethical preferences of the investor.

The method uses a scale of seven linguistic labels that allow the investor to express the importance she gives to each characteristic considered in the evaluation of the funds and, in a similar way, the degree to which these funds meet each of these characteristics.

A fuzzy score is obtained for each fund aggregating by means of fuzzy arithmetic the weights and the compliance with the characteristics. Thus what we shall call the fuzzy SR Quality of the fund is determined. With the purpose of obtaining a real number comprised between 0 and 1 in order to represent the ethical quality of the fund we construct a satisfaction set and the fuzzy SR Quality of the fund is evaluated on this.

The construction of the SR Quality indicator of a fund consists of five steps that we shall now describe:

1. Select the characteristics of social responsibility in order to evaluate the universe of funds (see Table A4). These characteristics which we have taken as reference are set out in the EIRIS Green and Ethical Funds Directory and are the ones which are most often included in the investment policies of this type of funds (see Bilbao-Terol et al., 2012).

2. Determine a weight, wj, for each characteristic in accordance with the considerations of the investor about the importance of same with respect to the social responsibility profile of the portfolio. We represent these weights by means of a linguistic scale (see Fig. 12) comprising seven labels: null, very low, low, medium, high, very high and total. These labels are defined by means of seven fuzzy triangular numbers whose support is the interval [0,10].

3. Evaluate compliance, Cj, of the fund i with each of the characteristics j selected in the first step. Therefore, Cj is a binary variable. An expert can undertake this evaluation using data provided by specialized organizations (e.g. Social Investment Forum (SIF), VIGEO and Morningstar Ltd.) and by means of the information contained in the fund reports (Table A5).

4. Determine the total fuzzy weighted score for each fund i.e. the fuzzy SR Quality of the fund. To do this we use fuzzy arithmetic: adding up for all the characteristics the weighted evaluations of the fund. Thus we obtain the fuzzy number s, with extremes a?, a? and kernel at2. The support of a will be contained in the interval [0, No. of characteristics x 10].

ai = W1Ci1 + W2cJ2 + • • • + W24Ci24 = (s^, a'2, a3)

5. Determine the SR Quality of the fund i. In order to define this crisp score we shall take into account the interests of the investor represented by a fuzzy goal and the value of the SR Quality fuzzy of ith fund: V(a-) (Delgado, Vila, & Voxman, 1998).

In order to construct a fuzzy goal it is necessary that the investor establishes the values of two parameters: g0 and g1. The first registers the minimum ethical quality below which the investor will obtain no satisfaction, on the opposite extreme, g1 registers the threshold upon which the investor expresses total satisfaction with the ethical quality of the fund. Therefore the following inequality must be verified: 0 < g0 < g1 < (No. of characteristics x 10).

The parameters g0 and g1 are determined by the level of exigency on the part of the investor regarding the social responsibility of the funds and also with regard to the characteristics in which she is interested - those with a no null weight. In this paper we have fixed the following values for both parameters (where NW represents the characteristics with null weight):

g0 = (No. of characteristics - No. of characteristics NW) x 1 =23 g1 = (No. of characteristics - No. of characteristics NW) x 8 = 184

that is, the investor will obtain a greater satisfaction than 0 provided that the fund achieves an aggregated score equal to the number of characteristics in which she is interested in, i.e. a mean of 1 in such characteristics and will feel totally satisfied if a mean of 8 as minimum is reached in such characteristics. Finally SR Quality of the fund i, ai, is obtained as the membership degree of V(Sj) in the fuzzy goal (Fig. 13). Therefore, the SR Quality of fund i is a number between 0 and 1.

Properties of the SR Quality

Here we display some ofthe properties ofthe proposed indicator which guarantee a modeling that is coherent with the preferences of the investor:

Fig. 12. The fuzzy weights.

'"I'lff^^B ARTICLE IN PRESS

A. Bilbao-Terol et al./ Revista de Contabilidad - Spanish Accounting Review xxx (xx) (2015) xxx-xxx

Fuzzy target

90 V (a¡) g1

Fig. 13. SR Quality for the ith mutual fund.

- The fuzzy SR Quality of the fund i increases with the weights and with the evaluation of compliance.

- The value of the fuzzy SR Quality of the fund i increases with movements of the support and the kernel toward the right (see Antomil Ibias, 2005).

- Set the parameters g0 and gi, the membership degree, ai, is no decreasing with V(a,).

- The movements toward the right of g0 and gl (increases the investor's exigency level) give a decreasing (no strict) of the SR Quality of the fund i.

We assume that the SR Quality is additive. Consequently, the SR Quality of portfolio x is given by aggregating the SR Quality of the component funds:

Qsr (x) = aPrx

This linearity hypothesis (see Barracchini, 2007; Scholtens, 2009; Drut, 2010a, 2010b) is often used by practitioners to SR-rate financial indices.

The two objectives (financial and ethical ones) are incorporated in a GP model, that will be formulated following.

Fig. 14. Aspiration level for the SR Quality goal.

Once defined the goals and the constraints included in the set X we propose the following GP model in order to obtain the SR portfolio tracking the reference one.

min »cVaR PcVaR + in + ®QsR PQsj

£ + J(1 fl,)y~/j + nCVaR - PcVaR = ALCVaR

J(1 -fl)

(P-Weighted GP)

^Pijx+nj - pj = J2j, j =1,

i=1 keCF

QSR(x) + nQsR -pQsr =alQSR

nj, Pj, nQSR , pqsr , ncVaR, PcVaR, Zj >0

4.2.3. GP model for SR-portfolio selection

In order to use a GP approach for a multi-objective problem it is necessary that the DM establishes aspiration levels for each goal (Ignizio, 1976; Tamiz, Jones, & Romero, 1998). For the portfolio values on each scenario these levels are the corresponding values of the reference portfolio; for the CVaR the level of aspiration (ALCVaR) can be fixed as the CVaR of a portfolio which follows that of the reference one but without taking into account its ethical quality. It is also possible that this level of aspiration could have been proposed by the investor herself.

In order to fix the level of aspiration of the goal associated with the ethical quality of the portfolio, we propose to interact with the investor in two points. Firstly, we construct a "smooth" satisfaction function in function of the maximum and minimum values of the SR Quality in the universe of the funds (see Fig. 14): ia0 > mina,- x C0 and ia1 < maxai x C0.

The second interaction with the investor consists in her fixing a degree of satisfaction fi by means of which the aspiration level (AL) for SR Quality goal is obtained in the following way: AL is the value in interval [iao, ia1 ] such that its membership degree to fuzzy goal is equal to fi (see Fig. 14).

4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 20 CVaR

Fig. 15. Efficient frontier of SR funds.

ARUdE IN PRESS

A. Bilbao-Terol et al./ Revista de Contabilidad - Spanish Accounting Review xxx (xx) (2015) xxx-xxx

Table 6

The efficient values CVaR and EVE (SR funds).

Portfolio CVaR EVE Portfolio CVaR EVE

1 2.4509 100.2351 21 10.7232 100.5829

2 2.4944 100.2525 22 11.2706 100.6002

3 2.775 100.2699 23 11.8215 100.6176

4 3.1025 100.2873 24 12.3726 100.635

5 3.4719 100.3046 25 12.9315 100.6524

6 3.8594 100.322 26 13.4924 100.6698

7 4.2591 1QQ.3394 27 14.0547 100.6872

8 4.6626 100.3568 28 14.619 100.7046

9 5.0743 100.3742 29 15.186 100.722

10 5.4921 100.3916 30 15.7615 1QQ.7393

11 5.9134 100.409 31 16.3396 100.7567

12 6.3438 100.4264 32 16.9203 100.7741

13 6.779 100.4438 33 17.5047 100.7915

14 7.2204 100.4611 34 18.0892 100.8089

15 7.6661 100.4785 35 18.6745 100.8263

16 8.136 100.4959 36 19.2606 100.8437

17 8.6262 1QQ.5133 37 19.8498 100.8611

18 9.1323 100.5307 38 820.4428 100.8785

19 9.6536 100.5481 39 21.0414 100.8958

20 10.1833 100.5655 40 21.6402 100.9132

Table 7

The composition of the first portfolio of the efficient frontier. Composition (money) of the portfolio with minimum CVaR

Inveractivo Confianza FI Santander Responsabilidad Coservd FI

12.7374 87.2626

5. Results

We present in Fig. 15 the efficient frontier respect to the two financial objectives, CVaR (relative to the net profits) and VFE.

The efficient values CVaR and EVE appear collected in Table 6. The outperformance of the conventional funds relative to the SR funds is noticed. The conventional efficient frontier is above that SR one (by comparison of Table 2 with Table 6).

The composition of the first portfolio of the efficient frontier is given in Table 7, which shows the most similar financial parameters to the reference portfolio.

The SR Quality of each fund (with the parameters set by the investor) has been gathered in Table 8.

The parameters ia0 and ia1, which determine the function of satisfaction of the SR Quality have been set in the following way: ia0 = a6 x C0 = 15.7468, ia1 = maxa,- x C0 = 41.8831.

We present, in first place, the results when we take fi = 0.9, that is, the investor wishes to reach at least one degree of satisfaction of 0.9 in the SR Quality of her portfolio. This portfolio does not reach the level of aspiration relative to the CVaR but does with respect to the SR Quality; in 125 scenarios the SR Portfolio Value is less than the value of the reference portfolio minus the VaR and the Expected

Table 8

SR Quality of each fund.

Fund SR Quality

AC Responsable 30 FI 0.2229

BBK Solidaria FI 0.2495

BBVA Bolsa Desarrollo Sostenible FI Q.Q335

BNP Paribas Fondo Solidaridad FI 0.0016

Caixa Catalunya Europa Valor FI 0.21

Foncaixa Coop. Soc. Resp. Europa FI 0.1575

Foncaixa Priv. Fondo Act. Ético FI 0.2489

Fondo Solidario ProUnicef FI 0.2159

Gesbeta Compromiso Fondo Ético FI 0.2684

Inveractivo Confianza FI 0

Santander Dividendo Solidario FI 0.2489

Santander Responsabilidad Coservd FI 0.4188

Table 9

The composition of the SR portfolios.

Composition (money) of the SR portfolio (ß = 0.9) (ß = 0.2)

Inveractivo Confianza FI 6.2404 11.8157

Santander Responsabilidad Coservd FI 93.7597 88.1843

Table 10

The characteristics of the SR portfolios.

Characteristics of the SR portfolio (^ = 0.9) (ß = 0.2)

5th percentile values of the

distribution CVaR VaR

Average of the worst losses of the

portfolio SR Average ofthe reference portfolio

in the worst losses Frequency ofportfolio under

100-VaR ALCVaR ALQsr

SR Quality

Performance (EVE/CVaR)

100.2435(100.3054) 100.2363(100.3054) 98.2391 (99.0519) 98.2279(99.0519)

1.8624

1.40145

98.2688

1QQ.1312

125/2500 = 0.05 =

39.2695

39.2695 53.8249

1.8568 1.3923 98.3252

100.1821

125/2500 = 1- а 1.5

20.974

36.9343 53.9833

0.05 =

The values of the reference portfolio appear in brackets.

Value of the SR Portfolio in this situation is equal to 98.2688. As can be observed, the obtained portfolio is resembled the first portfolio of the financial efficient frontier (minimum CVaR), which is the most similar to the reference portfolio (see Table 7). If we consider fi = 0.2, the investor is less exigent in ethical quality and the financial results draw closer to those of the first portfolio of the efficient frontier (Tables 9 and 10). The low SR score of Inveractivo Confianza FI fund is balanced by the high SR score of the Santander Responsabilidad Coservd FI fund and the combination of these funds gives the financial values desired by the investor.

The values of the SR portfolio and the reference portfolio can be observed in Figs. 16 and 17.

Table 10 shows the financial cost of investing in SR funds. Both financial objectives, CVaR and EVE, are worse in the SR portfolio. However, the proposed modeling does its job: it finds the

700 710 720 730 740 750 760 770 780 790 800 Fig. 16. Comparison portfolios (^ = 0.9, periods 700-800).

'"I'ffW^^B ARTICLE IN PRESS

A. Bilbao-Terol etal./ Revista de Contabilidad - Spanish Accounting Review xxx (xx) (2015) xxx-xxx 15

Table 11

The composition of the SR portfolios.

Composition of the SR portfolio (? = 0.9) Composition ofthe SR portfolio (? = 0.2)

BBK Solidaria FI 11.5724 BBK Solidaria FI 2.6139

Foncaixa Priv. Fondo Act. Ético FI 0.43098 Fondo Solidario ProUnicef FI 12.6069

Fondo Solidario ProUnicef FI 15.7971 Inveractivo Confianza FI 9.0847

Gesbeta Compromiso Fondo Ético FI 2.1252 Santander Responsabilidad Coservd FI 75.6944

Inveractivo Confianza FI 7.8418

Santander Responsabilidad Coservd FI 62.2326

SR portfolio, the most similar to the preferred financial portfolio. The investor can now choose between investing in SR market attending to her SEE concerns or in conventional market with better economic reward and less risk. A possible decision framework where the investor separates her investment budget in two Mental Accounts (Thaler, 1999), one conventional and other SR, could also be addressed with this proposal.

As was aforementioned, it has not been proved the underper-formance of SR market anywhere, anytime; therefore the financial sacrifice found in this study is not extrapolated to any market. However, the usefulness of the proposed tool remains in any case of performance of the SR market with respect to the conventional one.

5.1. Sensitivity analysis

We make a sensitivity analysis supposing that the Santander Responsabilidad Coservd FI fund - which is the one with the higher SR Quality and figures in large proportion in all the portfolios because, furthermore, it is low risk - had a SR Quality equal to 0. We show below the portfolios obtained for fi = 0.9 and fi = 0.2 (Tables 11 and 12).

As can be appreciated, the change to the SR rating in the Santander Responsabilidad Coservd FI fund, modifies the portfolios in the sense that its weight in the portfolio diminishes where the investor is very exigent regarding the SR profile (fi = 0.9) and increases when such exigency is lowered, that is, in this case, the investor chooses between low risk and high SR Quality. The results obtained in this work show several features of the SR Spanish

Fig. 17. Comparison portfolios = 0.9, periods 1000-1100).

Table 12

The characteristics of the SR portfolios.

Characteristics ofSR portfolios (? = 0.9) (? = 0.2)

EVE 100.2398 (100.3054) 100.2396

5th percentile values ofthe 97.6235 (99.0519) 97.9544

distribution

CVaR 2.5 2.1

VaR 1.83915 1.55485

Average of the worst losses 97.2373 97.8328

ofthe portfolio SR

Average of the reference 99.7426 99.9372

portfolio in the worst

losses

Frequency of portfolio 125/2500 = 0.05 = 1 - fl 125/2500 = 0.05 = 1 - fl

under100-VaR

ALCVaR 2 2

ALQsr 39.2695 39.2695

SR Quality 6.9752 3.374

The values of the reference portfolio appear in brackets.

market. Our SRI financial market did not have the high levels of development seen in other European financial markets, such as France, Italy or the Netherlands, where interest in SRI began during 1999 (EUROSIF, 2012). Spain is one of the European countries with the lowest volume of capital invested in SRI mutual funds. One of the most limiting factors that may explain the underde-velopment of SRI market is that Spanish SRI financial market does not take into account the investor preferences (Bilbao-Terol and Canal-Fernández, 2014).

^llHW^^B IIIII.E IN PRESS

16 A. Bilbao-Terol etal./ Revista de Contabilidad - Spanish Accounting Review xxx (xx) (2015) xxx-xxx

6. Conclusions

The new approach of investing, the SRI, attracts to a great number of investors and this fact should be taken into account by researches in financial fields in order to propose new methodologies for supporting to this class of investors. Investors in SRI funds pursue two types of goals: the economic rational goal of wealth-maximization and social responsibility. SRI investors are socially conscious and derive non-financial utility by holding assets consistent with their ethical and social values.

In this contribution, we present a model in the framework of SRI. Our proposal for selecting portfolios of SRI mutual funds uses copula functions in order to model the dependence structure of the fund returns. Furthermore, the modeling evaluates the ethical degree of the obtained portfolio. The financial performance of the SR portfolio is assessed against a portfolio made up of conventional mutual funds.

Our proposal is based on the most recent methodologies that have burst into the financial research as well as the practitioners. Behavioral Finance is a new paradigm in Decision Theory. Downside risk measures are institutionally supported by Basel Accords and by financial practice, such as private banking and financial and risk management. Copula Theory is a useful tool for multivariate modeling in financial markets. Using Fuzzy Set Theory could be more surprising into a financial framework; we have taken advantage of this methodology in order to model the imprecise preferences of the SR investors with respect to the different characteristics encompassed in the SR concept.

The good results obtained through the application ofthe Copula Theory for the estimation of the joint distribution of assets allow us to conclude that this theory is very useful for solving the portfolio selection even without very small number of assets. A convenient property of the model proposed is that it is not necessary to work with the same class of distribution for the marginals. Copula Theory gives a flexible tool that models the tail dependence that is present in the financial markets.

The emergence of the Behavioral Finance has been attended by the design of a portfolio selection model. Thus, Prospect Theory has been used in order to define the optimality of the reference portfolio: a utility function with S-shaped and setting the reference point as the capital that is invested at the beginning of the holding period and a downside risk measure, the CVaR relative to net profits.

With our model the investor knows the financial sacrifice she takes on by investing in funds classified as socially responsible and we proved that financial loss is associated with the trio returns, risk and ethical quality. The occurrence and valuation of this financial loss are a major concern of the SR investment market; therefore, we consider it useful to have a tool that evaluates this possible cost and tries to minimize it. The joint use of the CVaR associated with the loss relative to the reference portfolio and the comparison of two portfolios on each scenario allows us to model the problem of tracking.

In managing the ethical preferences of the investor, which are usually expressed in linguistic terms, the Fuzzy Set Theory has been shown to be especially useful. Notice that there is not a standard profile for this class of investors; therefore an analysis of their particular attention to the ethical values is necessary. Then they can be more comfortable evaluating the SR issues by linguistic labels and flexible graduations. The Fuzzy Set Theory has shown its power in these situations where imprecise judgments should be tackled. Due to this Fuzzy Technology has been used in a broad field of applications. Goal Programming has allowed a joint treatment of all the objectives of the investor. This methodology allows the interaction of the investor in two aspects of the problem: setting the aspiration

levels - in this model for the ethical quality and for the CVaR - and weighing the objectives.

The results obtained in this work should lead to a reflection about the SR Spanish market. It likes more inefficient than those of its neighbors. Spanish SRI financial market had not the high levels of development seen in other European financial markets, such as France, Italy or the Netherlands, where interest in SRI began during 1999. Spain is one of the European countries with the lowest volume of capital invested in SRI mutual funds. The constraint facing this research is the small number of SRI funds in Spain. In this sense, our objective in future researches is to work with European SRI funds (Eurozone, UK), where the SR investment universe is much broader; to extend the time period and to study the performance of SRI during the financial crisis. Moreover, the studied Spanish SRI funds have a strong religious component. It would be interesting to analyze whether the Spanish SRI funds today have expanded their range of social concerns.

Some of the limitations and extensions of this study which could be included in future research are commented below.

In order to reduce the computational burden, the obtaining of the reference portfolio could be replaced either the use of only one conventional market index or by the obtaining of a portfolio composed by several conventional market indexes. The conventional market indexes could behave as proxies for the reference portfolio. In this case, the construction is easier either because it would not be necessary to run the Stage 1, or the number of assets is drastically reduced in it.

It would be possible to use GARCH models to solve het-eroskedasticity problems, jointly with Copula Theory. We try to estimate the suitable copula for modeling the dependence structure between the corresponding filtered returns. In addition, the performance of Arquimedean copulas could be analyzed as an alternative to t-copulas utilized in the current study.

Regarding the modeling of social preferences of investors, it would be interesting to consider other aggregators - different from the sum, and other functions of satisfaction in the design of the SR Quality of each fund. Aggregation by weighted sum of the sustainable characteristics fulfilled by the Funds involves a compensation between them in order to investors with very intransigent ethical principles may not be appropriate. In this case, modeling ethical preferences of the investor would be more complicated. In this article, we have worked with binary variables to represent the fulfillment of the ethical characteristics of the funds. It would be also possible to use a graduated scale for such compliance.

The extension of the model to stock markets and domestic and foreign public debt would lead, in the first case, the search for information on compliance with sustainability criteria by companies. To do so, we would resort to their CSR reports. In the case of sovereign debt, the sustainable development indexes (ANS, EPI, HDI, ECF, Corruption Index, etc.) would be used.

Conflict of interest

The authors declare no conflict of interest.

Acknowledgments

We would like to thank the anonymous referees for their valuable comments and suggestions. The authors wish to gratefully acknowledge the financial support from the Spanish Ministry of Education, Project ECO2011-26499.

'"I'WW^^B AIIIIII .E IN PRESS

Appendix.

A. Bilbao-Terol et al./ Revista de Contabilidad - Spanish Accounting Review xxx (xx) (2015) xxx-xxx

BNP Paribas Fondo Solidaridad FI

AC responsable 30 FI

7.2 7 6.8 6.6 6.4 6.2 6 5.8 5.6 5.4 5.2

Oct05 May06 Nov06 Jun07 Dec07 Jul08 Jan09 Aug09 Mar10 Fig. A1. Time series of AC Responsable30 FI.

BBK solidaria FI

r w\ i i

""1........!.......... 1 : 1 ;

"Î.......¡.......... ... .......I..........

Vi / r*......

6.7 6.6 6.5 6.4 6.3 6.2 6.1

5.8 5.7

Oct05 May06 Nov06 Jun07 Dec07 Jul08 Jan09 Aug09 Mar10 Fig. A2. Time series of BBK Solidaria FI.

BBVA Bolsa Desarrollo Sostenible FI

«ß i!::

, / ). A ! i yv

•A y \\* X

h J I ; .......i......(ft-

V : r : i

■ •i.....

14 13 12 11 10 9 8 7 6 5

Oct05 May06 Nov06 Jun07 Dec07 Jul08 Jan09 Aug09 Mar10 Fig. A3. Time series of BBVA Bolsa Desarrollo Sostenible FI.

la.......

J fT"\"/ Y u

V ........t

\A Ají.

i ^vv

IA. k W i /

/ U V

V 1, A H\

• i i

Wl/l /

"l ; V

Oct05 May06 Nov06 Jun07 Dec07 Jul08 Jan09 Aug09 Mar10 Fig. A4. Time series of BNP Paribas Solidaridad FI.

Caixa Catalunya Europa Valor FI

/' ¿Vi / rt A '1/

w w ■■TT— i y V1 ( i / . i jfl /

\ / 1

► í V

Oct05 May06 Nov06 Jun07 Dec07 Jul08 Jan09 Aug09 Mar10 Fig. A5. Time series of Caixa Catalunya Europa Valor FI.

Foncaixa Coop. Soc Resp. Europa FI

7 6.5 6 5.5 5 4.5 4 3.5 3 2.5

Oct05 May06 Nov06 Jun07 Dec07 Jul08 Jan09 Aug09 Mar10 Fig. A6. Time series of Foncaixa Coop. Soc. Resp. Europa FI.

V i..........

V \ ,,/vl

"1 /

IIHBi^^M IIIII.E IN PRESS

A. Bilbao-Terol et al./ Revista de Contabilidad - Spanish Accounting Review xxx (xx) (2015) xxx-xxx Foncaixa Priv. Fondo Act. Ético FI Inveractivo Confianza FI

0ct05 May06 Nov06 Jun07 Dec07 Jul08 Jan09 Aug09 Mar10 Fig. A7. Time series of Foncaixa Priv. Fondo Act. Ético FI.

/ i y /

f f * I L J\

A .........1" i / I / H,

0ct05 May06 Nov06 Jun07 Dec07 Jul08 Jan09 Aug09 Mar10 Fig. A10. Time series of Interactivo Confianza FI.

Fondo Solidario ProUnicef FI

Santander Dividendo Solidario FI

/ 'V S J

A N ...........:..........Yrt...... i W \ t *

y ...........;......Al .........fl

\ \ r 11 v

0ct05 May06 Nov06 Jun07 Dec07 Jul08 Jan09 Aug09 Mar10 Fig. A8. Time series of Fondo Solidario ProUnicef FI.

f wv \

V y\

v ; \ A ...........L/„

Aw .......i... f, KÂ..........

I / 1 / ; V :

0ct05 May06 Nov06 Jun07 Dec07 Jul08 Jan09 Aug09 Mar10 Fig. A11. Time series of Santander Dividendo Solidario FI.

Gesbeta Compromiso Fondo Etico FI

6.6 6.4 6.2 6 5.8 5.6 5.4 5.2 5

Santander Responsabilidad Coservd FI

y ; i ;

/ ftiï / WTl :

/ ...........IV.......i............i............ ; -, \ ;

V' i W \ A........1............

...........:...........l 1 ^ 1 :

lí/V^

0ct05 May06 Nov06 Jun07 Dec07 Jul08 Jan09 Aug09 Mar10 Fig. A9. Time series of Gesbeta Compromiso Fondo Ético FI.

1 i IM1

iJ i..

J A 1 V

r1 jX V ff

V J . r ■ !

0ct05 May06 Nov06 Jun07 Dec07 Jul08 Jan09 Aug09 Mar10 Fig. A12. Time series of Santander Responsabilidad Conservd FI.

G Model

RCSAR-54; No. of Pages 22

ARTICLE IN PRESS

A. Bilbao-Terol etal. / Revista de Contabilidad - Spanish Accounting Review xxx (xx) (2015) xxx-xxx 19

Table A1

Fund name and investment policy (Spanish Association of Investment and Pension Funds, INVERCO).

Fund Type of fund* Q1 Q22 Q3 Mean Skewness Kurtosis

Banif Estructurado FI RVIO -0.0132 0.0014 0.01б2 0.0004 -0.47б2 4.9922

AC Fonandalucía Mixto FI RVIO -0.0026 0.0014 0.0039 0.000б -0.б112 4.5814

Caixa Galicia Mix 25 FI RVIE -0.0041 0.0012 0.0052 0.0002 -0.5338 3.908

Caixasabadell 6 Mixt FI RVIO -0.004 0.0014 0.0057 0.0004 -0.53б3 4.0б8б

Caja Badajoz Inversión FI RVIO -0.0043 0.0015 0.0058 0.0005 -0.5045 3.8379

Caja Ingenieros Europa 25 FI RFMI -0.0034 0.0005 0.0047 0.0001 -0.8б93 5.3414

Caja Ingenieros Global FI RVMI -0.0139 0.0007 0.0111 -0.0005 0.1244 5.б42б

Caja Ingenieros Multifondo FI FGL -0.0113 0.0017 0.0124 -0.0002 -0.342б 4.217б

Caja Madrid Evolución Var3 FI FGL -0.000б 0.000б 0.0014 0.0004 -0.9212 5.б002

Caja Madrid Evolución VaR 6 FI FGL -0.0013 0.000б 0.0019 0.0001 -1.3177 8.1738

Cajaburgos Mixto I FI FGL -0.0035 0.000б 0.0042 0.0001 -0.3977 3.39б7

BBK Fondo Internacional FI RFM -0.0118 0.001 0.0131 -0.000б -0.3351 5.б47

BBK Gestión Activa 15 FI RVMI -0.0018 0.000б 0.0027 0.0005 0.1553 4.1452

BBK Renta Global FI RFMI -0.0004 0.0004 0.0014 0.0005 -0.0022 4.0319

BBVA Bolsa Asia MFFI RVIO -0.0155 0.0022 0.0179 0.0013 0.081 4.8395

BBVA Bolsa Europa FI FGL -0.01б5 0.002 0.0172 0 0.0583 б.бб85

BBVA Bolsa Finanzas FI FGL -0.0234 -0.0012 0.0177 -0.0029 -0.1б75 8.20б3

BBVA Gestión Conservadora FI FGL -0.0029 0.001 0.0034 0.0002 0.0811 5.0554

BBVA Gestión Decidida FI FGL -0.0108 0.0014 0.0118 0.0001 -0.1248 3.б329

Table A2

Fund name and investment policy (CNMV).

Fund Type of fund* Q1 Q2 Q3 Mean Skewness Kurtosis

Beta Alpha Dinámico FI FGL -0.0022 0.0008 0.0038 0.000б 0.25б7 5.4371

BNP Paribas Conservador FI RVIO -0.0025 0.0012 0.0043 0.0005 -0.3911 4.4904

BNP Paribas Dinámico FI FGL -0.0109 0.0004 0.0098 -0.0001 -0.0453 4.8294

BNP Paribas Equilibrado FI RFM -0.0082 0.0002 0.007б -0.0001 -0.0797 4.4б98

BNP Paribas Gestión Activa FI FGL -0.005 0.0013 0.0053 0.0002 -0.2121 4.5994

BNP Paribas Global III FI RFM -0.002б 0.001 0.0043 0.000б -0.3203 3.749б

BNP Paribas Global Investment FI FGL -0.0075 0.0013 0.0081 -0.0002 -0.203б 5.133

BNP Paribas Inversión FI FGL -0.0091 0.0011 0.0092 -0.0009 -0.3б85 3.7107

BNP Paribas Management Fund FI FGL -0.0024 0.0008 0.0038 0.0005 -0.343 4.435

BNP Paribas Protected Plus FI RVIO -0.0014 0.0004 0.0031 0.0004 -0.8389 5.9822

Bomerbe FI FGL -0.017 0.002 0.0171 0.0001 -0.0893 4.б991

CAI Renta Mixto 20 FI FGL -0.0031 0.001 0.0044 0.0003 -0.4881 4.0553

Caixa Catalunya Dinámico 2 FI FGL -0.0088 0.0004 0.0102 -0.000б -0.7037 4.2897

Caixa Catalunya Dinámico FI FGL -0.0095 0.0005 0.0102 -0.000б -0.б327 4.3539

Caixa Catalunya Equilibrio 2 FI FGL -0.00б1 0.0003 0.005б -0.0003 -0.54б4 3.9085

Caixa Catalunya Equilibrio FI FGL -0.00б 0.0004 0.0057 -0.0003 -0.5088 3.8411

AC Australasia FI RVIE -0.0179 -0.0009 0.014 -0.0011 0.3134 3.б79б

AC Fondtesoro Plus FI RVIE -0.0024 0.0013 0.0041 0.000б -0.8015 5.7919

AC Inversión Selectiva FI FGL -0.0145 0.0032 0.0218 0.0019 0.0б25 5.24б3

* FGL (Global Fund); RFM (Mixed Fixed-Income); RFMI (International Mixed Fixed-Income); RVIE (Euro Zone Balanced Equity fund); RVMI (International Variable Mixed Income); RVIO (International Variable Income).

Table A3

Dates of minimum and maximum price of the SR fund.

Fund Day ofminimum price Day ofmaximum price

F1 AC Responsable 30 FI 09/03/2009 1б/07/2007

F2 BBK Solidaria FI 09/03/2009 31/10/2007

F3 BBVA Bolsa Desarrollo Sostenible FI 09/03/2009 15/0б/2007

F4 BNP Paribas Fondo Solidaridad FI 09/03/2009 01/0б/2007

F5 Caixa Catalunya Europa Valor FI 21/11/2008 14/10/2009

F6 Foncaixa Coop. Soc. Resp. Europa FI 09/03/2009 01/0б/2007

F7 Foncaixa Priv. Fondo Act. Ético FI 09/03/2009 31/10/2007

F8 Fondo Solidario ProUnicefFI 0б/03/2009 17/07/2007

F9 Gesbeta Compromiso Fondo Ético FI 27/10/2008 01/0б/2007

F10 Inveractivo Confianza FI 14/0б/200б 01/0б/2007

F11 Santander Dividendo Solidario FI 09/03/2009 01/0б/2007

F12 Santander Responsabilidad Coservd FI 08/0б/200б 29/12/2009

'МИШ^^И IIIII.E IN PRESS

20 A. Bilbao-Terol etal./ Revista de Contabilidad - Spanish Accounting Review xxx (xx) (2015) xxx-xxx

Table A4

Fulfillment matrix of the characteristics of social responsibility of the funds.

Group I: Social Group II: Environmental Group III: Ethical

1 Bribery and corruption 12 Environmental management, policy, reporting and performance 17 Intensive farming and meat sale

2 Community involvement 13 Climate change and greenhouse gases 18 Breast milk substitutes

3 Equal opportunities 14 Nuclear power 19 Tobacco marketing

4 SEE Risk Management 15 Pollution 20 Military issues

5 Women on the board 1б Genetic engineering 21 Alcohol and gambling

б Human rights 22 Abortion

7 Relationships with customers and suppliers 23 Contraception

8 Supply chains 24 Pornography and adult entertainment services

9 Trade unions

10 Training and development

11 Positive products and services

Table A5

Fulfillment matrix of the characteristics of social responsibility of the funds.

Fund Criteria

1 2 3 4 5 б 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 1б 17 18 19 20 21 22 23 24

F1 0 1 1 1 0 1 1 0 1 1 0 0 1 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0

F2 0 0 1 1 1 1 0 0 0 0 0 1 1 0 1 0 0 0 1 1 1 0 0 0

F3 0 1 0 1 0 0 1 0 0 1 0 1 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0

F4 0 1 1 0 0 1 0 0 0 1 0 1 0 0 1 0 0 0 1 1 1 0 0 1

F5 0 1 0 1 0 0 1 0 1 1 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 1 1 1 0 0 0

F6 1 0 0 0 0 1 1 1 1 1 0 1 0 1 0 0 0 0 1 1 0 0 0 0

F7 0 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 0 1 0 1 0 0 0 1 1 1 0 0 0 0

F8 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 1 1 1 0 0 0

F9 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1

F10 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1

F11 0 0 1 0 0 0 0 0 0 1 1 1 1 0 1 0 0 0 0 1 0 1 0 0

F12 1 0 1 0 0 1 0 0 0 0 0 1 1 0 1 1 0 0 0 1 1 1 1 0

References

Abdelaziz, F. B., Aouni, B., & el Fayedh, R. (2007). Multi-objective stochastic programming for portfolio selection. European Journal of Operational Research, 177(3), 1811-1823.

Ang, A., & Bekaert, G. (2002). International asset allocation with regime shifts. Review of Financial Studies, 15(4), 1137-1187.

Ang, A., & Chen, J. (2002). Asymmetric correlations of equity portfolios. Journal of Financial Economics, 63(3), 443-494.

Ang, A., Chen, J., & Xing, Y. (2006). Downside risk. Review of Financial Studies, 19(4), 1191-1239.

Antomil Ibias, J. (2005). Análisis y Gestión de Carteras con Metodología Posibilística. Aplicación a los Fondos de Inversión Mobiliaria Españoles (Tesis doctoral). Facultad de Economía y Empresa, Universidad de Oviedo.

Aouni, B., Colapino, C., & La Torre, D. (2014). Financial portfolio management through the goal programming model: Current state-of-the-art. European Journal of Operational Research, 234(2), 536-545.

Arenas Parra, M., Bilbao Terol, A., & Rodriguez Uría, M. V. (2001). A fuzzy goal programming approach to portfolio selection. European Journal of Operational Research, 133, 287-297.

Artzner, P., Delbaen, F., Eber, J., & Heath, D. (1999). Coherent measures of risk. Mathematical Finance, 9, 203-288.

Ballestero, E., Bravo, M., Perez-Gladish, B., Arenas-Parra, M., & Pla-Santamaria, D. (2012). Socially responsible investment: A multicriteria approach to portfolio selection combining ethical and financial objectives. European Journal of Operational Research, 216, 487-494.

Barracchini, C. (2007). An ethical investments evaluation for portfolio selection. Electronic Journal of Business Ethics and Organization Studies, 12(2) http://ejbo.jyu.fi/articles/090K1.html

Basel Committee on Banking Supervision. (2001, January). The new base capital accord. Basel Committee Publications.

Basel Committee on Banking Supervision, Basel III. (2011). A global regulatory framework for more resilient banks and banking systems. Basel Committee Publications.

Basso, A., & Funari, S. (2014). Constant and variable returns to scale DEA models for socially responsible investment funds. European Journal of Operational Research, 235(3), 775-783.

Beine, M. (2004). Conditional covariances and direct central bank interventions in the foreign exchange markets. Journal of Banking and Finance, 28(6), 1385-1411.

Beine, M., Cosma, A., & Vermeulen, R. (2010). The dark side of global integration: Increasing tail dependence. Journal of Banking and Finance, 34(1), 184-192.

Bellman, R. E., & Zadeh, L. A. (1970). Decision-making in a fuzzy environment. Management Science, 17(4), 141-164.

Bello, Z. Y. (2005). Socially responsible investing and portfolio diversification. Journal of Financial Research, XXVIII, 41-57.

Biehl, C. F., Dumke, M., Hoepner, A. G. F., & Wilson, J. O. S. (2010, December). SRI funds: Does more social mean less financial performance? http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.1726146. Available from SSRN http://ssrn.com/abstra01726146

Bilbao, A., Arenas, M., Rodríguez, M. V., & Antomil, J. (2007). On constructing expert betas for single-index model. European Journal of Operational Research, 183, 827-847.

Bilbao-Terol, A., Arenas-Parra, M., & Canal-Fernández, V. (2012). Selection of socially responsible portfolios using goal programming and fuzzy technology. Information Sciences, 189,110-125.

Bilbao-Terol, A., Arenas-Parra, M., Canal-Fernández, V., & Bilbao-Terol, C. (2013). Selection of socially responsible portfolios using hedonic prices. Journal of Business Ethics, 115(3), 515-529.

Bilbao-Terol, C., & Canal-Fernández, V. (2014). The market valuation of ethical assets in Spain: An application of the hedonic pricing method. Business Ethics: A European Review, 23(4), 343-363.

Boubaker, H., & Sghaier, N. (2013). Portfolio optimization in the presence of dependent financial returns with long memory: A copula based approach. Journal of Banking & Finance, 37(2), 361-377.

Bouyé, E., Durrleman, V., Nikeghbali, A., Riboulet, G., & Roncalli, T. (2001). Copulas: An open field for risk management. Groupe de Recherche Opérationnelle, Crédit Lyonnais, Working Paper. http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.1032557. Available from SSRN http://ssrn.com/abstra01032557 Accessed 20.03.14

Brooks, C., Burke, P., Heravi, S., & Persand, S. G. (2005). Autoregressive conditional kurtosis. Journal of Financial Econometrics, 3(3), 399-421.

Caballero, R., Luque, M., Jolina, J., & Ruiz, F. (2005). MOPEN: A computational package for linear multiobjective and goal programming problems. Decision Support Systems, 41(1), 160-175.

Caballero, R., Gómez, T., & Ruiz, F. (2009). Goal programming: Realistic targets for the near future. Journal of Multi-criteria Decision Analysis, 16(3-4), 79-110.

Cabello, J. M., Ruiz, F., Pérez-Gladish, B., & Méndez-Rodríguez, P. (2014). Synthetic indicators of mutual funds' environmental responsibility: An application of the Reference Point Method. European Journal of Operational Research, 236(1), 313-325.

Capelle-Blancard, G., & Monjon, S. (2014). The performance of socially responsible funds: Does the screening process matter? European Financial Management, 20(3), 494-520.

Chang, C. T. (2007). Multi-choice goal programming. Omega, 35(4), 389-396.

'"I'WW^^B "IIIIII .E IN PRESS

A. Bilbao-Terol etal./ Revista de Contabilidad - Spanish Accounting Review xxx (xx) (2015) xxx-xxx 21

Charlo Molina, M. J., & Moya Clemente, I. (2010). El comportamiento financiero de las empresas Socialmente Responsables. Investigaciones Europeas de Dirección y Economía de la Empresa, ¡6(2), 15-25.

Charnes, A., Cooper, W. W., & Ferguson, R. (1955). Optimal estimation of executive compensation by linear programming. Management Science, ¡, 138-151.

Charnes, A., & Cooper, W. W. (1961). Management models and industrial applications of linear programming. New York: John Wiley and Sons.

Cherubini, U., Luciano, E., & Vecchiato, W. (2004). Copula methods in finance. New York: Wiley.

Cintas del Río, R. (2007). Teoría de Cópulas y Control de Riesgo Financiero (Tesis Doctoral). Facultad de Ciencias Matemáticas, Universidad Complutense de Madrid., ISBN 978-84-669-3132-8

Das, S. R., & Uppal, R. (2004). Systemic risk and international portfolio choice. Journal of Finance, 59(6), 2809-2834.

Delgado, M., Vila, M. A., & Voxman, W. (1998). On a canonical representation of fuzzy numbers. Fuzzy Sets and Systems, 93,125-135.

Demarta, S., & McNeil, A. (2005). The t copula and related copulas. International Statistical Review, 73(1), 111-129.

Derwall, J., & Koedijk, K. (2009). Socially responsible fixed-income funds. Journal of Business Finance & Accounting, 36, 210-229.

Dias, A., & Embrechts, P. (2004). Dynamic copula models for multivariate high-frequency data in Finance. Discussion paper. ETH Zürich. Available from http://citeseerx.ist.psu.edu/viewdoc/download?doi=10.1.1.197.5014&rep= rep1&type=pdf Accessed 20.03.14

Dorfleitner, G., & Utz, S. (2012). Safety first portfolio choice based on financial and sustainability returns. European Journal of Operational Research, 221(1), 155-164.

Drut, B. (2010a). Sovereign bonds and socially responsible investment. Journal of Business Ethics, 92, 131-145.

Drut, B. (2010b). Social responsibility and mean-variance portfolio selection, no. ¡0002, RS, Working Papers CEB from Université Libre de Bruxelles, Solvay Bruxelles School of Economics and Management, Centre Emile Bernheim (CEB).

Embrechts, P., Lindskog, F., & McNeil, A. (2001). Modelling dependence with copulas and applications to risk management. Zürich: Department of Mathematics ETHZ. Available from http://www.math.ethz.ch/~embrecht/ftp/copchapter.pdf Accessed 20.03.14

Embrechts, P., McNeil, A. J., & Straumann, D. (1999). Correlation: Pitfalls and alternatives a short. Risk, ¡2(5), 69-71.

Embrechts, P., McNeil, A. J., & Straumann, D. (2002). Correlation and dependence in risk management: Properties and pitfalls. In M. Dempster (Ed.), Risk management: Value at risk and beyond (pp. 176-223). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

EUROSIF. (2012). European SRI study 2012. Paris: European Sustainable and Responsible Investment Forum.

Forbes, K. J., & Rigobon, R. (2000). No contagion, only interdependence: Measuring stock market comovements. Journal of Finance, LVII(5), 2223-2261.

Fung, M. V. (2006). Developments in behavioral finance and experimental economics and Post Keynesian finance theory. Journal of Post Keynesian Economics, 29(1), 19-39.

Galema, R., Plantinga, A., & Scholtens, B. (2008). The stocks at stake: Return and risk in socially responsible investment. Journal of Banking & Finance, 32(12), 2646-2654.

Gilboa, I. (2009). Theory of decision under uncertainty. New York: Cambridge University Press.

Gupta, P., Mehlawat, M. K., & Saxena, A. (2008). Asset portfolio optimization using fuzzy mathematical programming. Information Sciences, ¡78,1734-1755.

Gupta, P., Mehlawat, M. K., & Saxena, A. (2013). Hybrid optimization models of portfolio selection involving financial and ethical considerations Knowledge-Based Systems, 37,318-337.

Hallerbach, W., Ning, H., Soppe, A., & Spronk, J. (2004). A framework for managing a portfolio of socially responsible investments. European Journal of Operational Research, ¡53,517-529.

Haimes, Y. Y., Lasdon, L. S., & Wismer, D. A. (1971). On a bicriterion formulation of the problems of integrated systems identification and system optimization. IEEE Transactions on Systems, Man, and Cybernetics, ¡(3), 296-297.

Hartmann, P., Straeman, S., & de Vries, C. G. (2004). Asset market linkages in crisis periods. Review of Economics and Statistics, 86(1), 313-326.

Harvey, C. R., & Siddique, A. (1999). Autoregressive conditional skewness. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 34(4), 465-487.

Hong, H., & Kacperczyk, M. (2009). The price of sin: The effects of social norms on markets. Journal of Financial Economics, 93(1), 15-36.

Hong, Y., Tu, J., & Zhou, G. (2007). Asymmetries in stock returns: Statistical tests and economic evaluation. Review ofFinancial Studies, 20(5), 1547-1581.

Hsin-Hung, C. (2008). Value-at-risk efficient portfolio selection using goal programming. Review of Pacific Basin Financial Markets and Policies (RPBFMP), ¡¡(02), 187-200.

Huang, X. (2007). A new perspective for optimal portfolio selection with random fuzzy returns. Information Sciences, ¡77, 5404-5414.

Humphrey, J. E., & Lee, D. D. (2011). Australian socially responsible funds: Performance, risk and screening intensity. Journal ofBusiness Ethics, ¡02(4), 519-535.

Ignizio, J. P. (1976). Goal programming and extensions. Massachusetts: Lexington Books.

Joe, H. (1997). Multivariate models and dependence concepts. Capman & Hall.

Jondeau, E., Poon, S. H., & Rockinger, M. (2007). Financial modeling under non-Gaussian distributions. New York: Springer Verlag.

Jondeau, E., & Rockinger, M. (2003). Conditional volatility, skewness and kurtosis: Existence, persistence, and comovements. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 27(10), 1699-1737.

Jones, D. F., & Tamiz, M. (2010). Practical goal programming. New York: Springer.

Kahneman, D. (2000). A psychological point of view: Violations of rational rules as a diagnostic of mental processes. Behavioral and Brain Sciences, 23, 681-683.

Kahneman, D. (2002). Maps of bounded rationality: A perspective on intuitive judgment and choice. Prize Lecture, December, 8. Princeton, NJ, USA: Princeton University, Department of Psychology.

Kahneman, D., Knetsch, J. L., & Thaler, R. H. (1990). Experimental tests ofthe endowment effect and the Coase theorem. Journal ofPolitical Economy, 98, 1325-1348.

Kahneman, D., & Tversky, A. (1979). Prospect theory: An analysis of decision under risk. Econometrica, XVLII, 263-291.

Kaminski, B., Czupryna, M., & Szapiro, T. (2009). On conditional value-at-risk based goal programming portfolio selection procedure. In V. Barichard, M. Ehrgott, X. Gandibleux, & V. T'Kindt (Eds.), Multiobjective programming and goal programming (pp. 243-252). Springer.

Kaya, I., & Kahramana, C. (2010). Development of fuzzy process accuracy index for decision making problems. Information Sciences, ¡80, 861-872.

Keel, S. T. (2006). Optimal portfolio construction and active portfolio management including alternative investments. A dissertation submitted to the Swiss Federal Institute of Technology, Zurich., ISBN 978-3-906483-10-8.

Kempf, A., & Osthoff, P. (2007). The effect of socially responsible investing on portfolio performance. European Financial Management, ¡3(5), 908-922.

Krokhmal, P., Palmquist, J., & Uryasev, S. (2002). Portfolio optimization with conditional value-at-risk objective and constraints. Journal of Risk, 4(2), 43-68.

Kwiatkowski, D., Phillips, P., Schmidt, P., & Shin, Y. (1992). Testing the null hypothesis of stationary against the alternative of a unit root. How sure are we that economic series have a unit root? Journal ofEconometrics, 54, 159-178.

Lee, D. D., Humphrey, J. E., Benson, K. L., & Ahn, J. Y. K. (2010). Socially responsible investment fund performance: The impact of screening intensity. Accounting & Finance, 50(2), 351-370.

Lee, S. M., & Lerro, A.J. (1973). Optimizing the portfolio selection for mutual funds. Journal of Finance, XXVIII, 1087-1101.

Li, X.-M. (2011). How do exchange rates co-move? A study on the currencies of five inflation-targeting countries. Journal of Banking and Finance, 35(2), 418-429.

Malevergne, Y., & Sornette, D. (2003). Testing the Gaussian copula hypothesis for financial assets dependences. Quantitative Finance, 3, 231-250.

Markowitz, H. M. (1952). Portfolio selection. Journal of Finance, 7, 77-91.

Markowitz, H. M. (1959). Portfolio selection: Efficient diversification of investments. Nueva York: John Wiley & Sons.

Mason, C., Jason Shogren, C. S., & List, J. (2005). Investigating risky choices over losses using experimental data. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 3¡(2), 187-215.

McNeil, A., Frey, R., & Embrechts, P. (2005). Quantitative risk management: Concepts, techniques, and tools. Princeton University Press.

Meucci, A. (2006). Beyond Black-Litterman in practice. Risk, ¡9(9), 114-119.

Meucci, A. (2007). Risk and asset allocation. New York: Springer Verlag.

Merigó, J. M., & Gil-Fuente, A. M. (2010). New decision-making techniques and their application in the selection of financial products. Information Sciences, ¡80, 2085-2094.

Miralles Marcelo, J. L., Miralles Quirós, M., & Miralles Quirós, J. L. (2012). Performance bursátil de las empresas socialmente responsables. Stock return performance of socially responsible firms. Cuadernos de Economía y Dirección de la Empresa, ¡5(4), 221-230.

Nelsen, R. B. (1999). An introduction to copulas. New York: Springer Verlag.

Nevins, D. (2004). Goals-based investing: Integrating traditional and behavioral finance. Journal ofWealth Management, 6(4), 8-23.

Patton, A. (2004). On the out-of-sample importance of skewness and asymmetric dependence for asset allocation. Journal of Financial Econometrics, 2(1), 130-168.

Poon, S.-H., Rockinger, M., & Tawn, J. (2004). Modelling extreme-value dependence in international stock markets. Statistica Sinica, ¡3, 929-953.

Post, T., & van Vliet, P. (2004). Conditional downside risk and the CAPM. Workingpaper. Rotterdam: Erasmus University.

Rank, J. (2002). Improving VaR calculations by using copulas and non-gaussian margins (Doctoral thesis). New College, University of Oxford. Available from http://www.maths.ox.ac.uk/system/files/private/active/0/lmproving %20Value%20at%20Risk%20Calculations%20by%20Using%20Copulas %20and%20Non-Gaussian%20margins.pdf Accessed 20.03.14

Renneboog, L., Ter Horst, J., & Zhang, C. (2008a). Socially responsible investments: Institutional aspects, performance and investor behavior. Journal of Banking and Finance, 32(9), 1723-1742.

Renneboog, L., Ter Horst, J., & Zhang, C. (2008b). The price of ethics and stakeholder governance The performance of socially responsible mutual funds. Journal of Corporate Finance, ¡4(3), 302-322.

Renneboog, L., Ter Horst, J., & Zhang, C. (2011). Is ethical money financially smart? Nonfinancial attributes and money flows of socially responsible investment funds. Journal ofFinancial Intermediation, 20(4), 562-588.

Ricciardi, V. (2008). The financial psychology of worry and women. http://ssrn.com/abstra01093351 Accessed 01.03.14

Rivas, V., & Cuesta, A. (2006). A computational solution for generating claim sizes using Copula Theory. ln Proceedings of the 7th WSEAS international conference on mathematics & computers in business & economics, Cavtat, Croatia, June ¡3-¡5 (pp. 35-40).

Rockafellar, R., & Uryasev, S. (2000). Optimization of conditional value at-risk. Journal of Risk, 2,21-41.

МРИИ^^И IIIII.E IN PRESS

22 A. Bilbao-Terol etal./ Revista de Contabilidad - Spanish Accounting Review xxx (xx) (2015) xxx-xxx

Romano, C. (2002). Applying copula function to risk management. University of Rome, "La Sapienza", working paper. http://www.icer.it/workshop/Romano.pdf

Romero, C. (1991). Handbook of critical issues in goal programming. Oxford: Pergamon Press.

Romero, C. (2004). A general structure of achievement function for a goal programming model. European Journal of Operational Research, 153,675-686.

Roy, A. D. (1952). Safety first and the holding of assets. Econometrica, 20,431-449.

Sandberg, J.,Juravle, C., Hedesstrom, T. D., & Hamilton, I. (2009). The heterogeneity of socially responsible investment. Journal of Business Ethics, 87(4), 519-533.

Scholtens, B. (2009). Measuring sustainability performance of investments; the case of Dutch bond funds. Paper prepared for the PRI Academic Conference 2009. Available from http://www.unpri.org/files/Scholtens_PRI2009.pdf

Shiller, R. J. (2006). Tools for financial innovation: Neoclassical versus behavioral finance. Financial Review, 41(1), 1-8.

Shiller, R., & Thaler, R. (2007). Workshop in behavioral finance. http://www.econ.yale.edu/~shiller/behfin/index.htm

Silverman, B. W. (1986). Density estimation for statistics and data analysis. London: Chapman and Hall.

Simon, H. A. (1956). Rational choice and the structure ofthe environment. Psychological Review, 63(2), 129-138.

Sklar, A. (1959). Fonctions de répartition an dimensions et leurs marges. Publications de l'Institut de Statistique de l'Université de Paris, 8, 229-231.

Statman, M., & Glushkov, D. (2009). The wages of social responsibility. Financial Analysts Journal, 65(4), 33-46.

Steuer, R. E., Qi, Y., & Hirschberger, M. (2007). Suitable-portfolio investors, non-dominated frontier sensitivity, and the effect of multiple objectives on standard portfolio selection. Annals of Operations Research, 152, 297-317.

Tamiz, M., Jones, D. F., & Romero, C. (1998). Goal programming for decision making: An overview of the current state-of-the-art. European Journal of Operational Research, 111,569-581.

Thaler, R. H. (1999). Mental accounting matters. Journal of Behavioral Decision Making, 12,183-206.

Trenado, M., Romero, M., Cuadrado, M. L., & Romero, C. (2014). Corporate social responsibility in portfolio selection: A "goal games" against nature approach. Computers and Industrial Engineering, 75, 260-265.

Tversky, A., & Kahneman, D. (1992). Advances in prospect theory: Cumulative representation of uncertainty. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 5(4), 297-323.

Wakker, P. P., Timmermans, D. R. M., & Machielse, I. (2007). The effects of statistical information on risk- and ambiguity-attitudes, and on rational insurance decisions. Management Science, 53(11), 1770-1784.

Wu, L.-C., & Tsai, I.-C. (2014). Three fuzzy goal programming models for index portfolios. Journal ofthe Operational Research Society, 65(8), 1155-1169.

Zadeh, L. A. (1965). Fuzzy sets. Information and Control, 8,338-353.

Zhang, W. G., Wang, Y. L., Chen, Z. P., & Nie, Z. K. (2007). Possibilistic mean-variance models and efficient frontiers for portfolio selection problem. Information Sciences, 177,2787-2801.

Zopounidis, C., & Doumpos, M. (2013). Multicriteria decision systems for financial problems. TOP, 21(2), 241-261.