Scholarly article on topic 'Weak and strong mixed vector equilibrium problems on non-compact domain'

Weak and strong mixed vector equilibrium problems on non-compact domain Academic research paper on "Mathematics"

CC BY-NC-ND
0
0
Share paper
OECD Field of science
Keywords
{"Mixed vector equilibrium problem" / "Coercing family" / " C-convex" / "Generalized KKM principle"}

Abstract of research paper on Mathematics, author of scientific article — Mijanur Rahaman, Rais Ahmad

Abstract In this paper, we consider two mixed vector equilibrium problems i.e., a weak mixed vector equilibrium problem and a strong mixed vector equilibrium problem which are combinations of a vector equilibrium problem and a vector variational inequality problem. We prove existence results for both the problems in non-compact setting.

Academic research paper on topic "Weak and strong mixed vector equilibrium problems on non-compact domain"

Journal of the Egyptian Mathematical Society (2015) 23, 352-355

Egyptian Mathematical Society Journal of the Egyptian Mathematical Society

www.etms-eg.org www.elsevier.com/locate/joems

ORIGINAL ARTICLE

Weak and strong mixed vector equilibrium c^Ma*

problems on non-compact domain

Mijanur Rahaman *, Rais Ahmad

Department of Mathematics, Aligarh Muslim University, Aligarh 202002, India

Received 13 April 2014; revised 27 May 2014; accepted 3 June 2014 Available online 19 July 2014

KEYWORDS

Mixed vector equilibrium problem; Coercing family; C-convex;

Generalized KKM principle

Abstract In this paper, we consider two mixed vector equilibrium problems i.e., a weak mixed vector equilibrium problem and a strong mixed vector equilibrium problem which are combinations of a vector equilibrium problem and a vector variational inequality problem. We prove existence results for both the problems in non-compact setting.

2010 MATHEMATICS SUBJECT CLASSIFICATION: 47J20; 49J40; 90C33

© 2014 Production and hosting by Elsevier B.V. on behalf of Egyptian Mathematical Society.

1. Introduction

Many problems of practical interest in optimization, economics and engineering involve equilibrium in their description. The equilibrium problem was first introduced and studied by Blum and Oettli [1] as a generalization of variational inequality problem. It has been shown that the equilibrium problem provides a natural, novel and unified framework to study a wide class of problems arising in nonlinear analysis, optimization, economics, finance and game theory. The equilibrium problem includes many mathematical problems as particular cases such as mathematical programming problems, complementarity problems, variational inequality problems, fixed point

problems, minimax inequality problems, and Nash equilibrium problems in noncooperative games. see [1-4].

Let X be a Hausdorff topological vector space, K be a subset of X, and f: K x K ! R be a mapping with f (x, x) = 0. The classical, scalar-valued equilibrium problem deals with the existence of x 2 K such that

f(x, y) p 0; 8y 2 K.

Moreover, in the case of vector valued mappings, let Y be a another Hausdorff topological vector space, C C Y a cone. Given a vector mapping f: K x K ! Y, then the problem of finding x 2 K such that

f(x, y) R —intC; 8y 2 K,

is called weak equilibrium problem and the point x 2 K is called weak equilibrium point, where intC denotes the interior of the cone C in Y.

In this paper, we consider two types of mixed vector equilibrium problems which are combinations of a vector equilibrium problem and a vector variational inequality problem. Let X and Y be two Hausdorff topological vector spaces. Let K be a nonempty convex closed subset of X and C # Y a

* Corresponding author. Tel.: +91 9897752840.

E-mail addresses: mrahman96@yahoo.com (M. Rahaman),

raisain_123@rediffmail.com (R. Ahmad).

Peer review under responsibility of Egyptian Mathematical Society.

Production and hosting by Elsevier

1110-256X © 2014 Production and hosting by Elsevier B.V. on behalf of Egyptian Mathematical Society. http://dx.doi.Org/10.1016/j.joems.2014.06.007

pointed closed convex cone with nonempty interior i.e., intC — £. The partial order "<C" on Y induced by C is defined by x <C y if and only if y — x 2 C. Let f: K x K ! Y and T: K ! L(X, Y) be two mappings, where L(X, Y) is the space of all linear continuous mappings from X to Y. Here (T(x), y) denotes the evaluation of the linear mapping T(x) at y. Now, we consider the following two problems: Find x 2 K such that

f(x,y) + (T(x),y — x) R —intC; 8y 2 K. (1.1)

f(x,y) + (T(x),y — x) R —C\{0}; 8y 2 K. (1.2)

We call problem (1.1) as weak mixed vector equilibrium problem and problem (1.2) as strong mixed vector equilibrium problem. Problems (1.1) and (1.2) are unified models of several known problems used in applied sciences, for instance, vector variational inequality problem, vector complementarity problem, vector optimization problem and vector saddle point problem, see e.g. [3,5-9] and references therein. For a more comprehensive bibliography on vector equilibrium problems, vector variational inequality problems and their generalizations, we refer to volume edited by Giannessi [3]. Our results generalize the results obtained by Blum and Oettli [1] and therefore the results of Fan [10] for vector valued mappings. For more details, we refer to [5,11,12]. As the underlying set K is non-compact, therefore we use only a very weak coercivity condition i.e., coercing family.

2. Preliminaries

The following definitions and results are needed in the sequel.

Definition 2.1. Let g : K ! Y be a mapping. Then g is said to be C-convex, if for all x,y 2 K and k 2 [0,1]

g(kx +(1 — k)y) <C kg(x) + (1 — k)g(y), which implies that

g(kx +(1 — k)y) 2 kg(x) + (1 — k)g(y) — C. Definition 2.2. A mapping g : K ! Y is said to be

(i) lower semicontinuous with respect to C at a point x0 2 K, if for any neighborhood V of g(x0) in Y, there exists a neighborhood U of x0 in X such that

g(UnK) C V + C;

(ii) upper semicontinuous with respect to C at a point

x0 2 K, if

g(U n K) C V — C;

(iii) continuous with respect to C at a point x0 2 K, if it is lower semicontinuous and upper semicontinuous with respect to C at that point.

Remark 2.1. If g is lower semicontinuous, upper semicontinu-ous and continuous with respect to C at any point of K, then g is lower semicontinuous, upper semicontinuous and continuous with respect to C on K, respectively.

Definition 2.3. A mapping f: K x K! Y is said to be C-monotone, if for all x, y 2 K

f(x, y)+f(y, x) 2 — C.

Lemma 2.1 [9]. f g is a lower semicowtinuous mapping with respect to C, then the set {x 2 K: g(x) R intC} is closed in K.

Lemma 2.2 [13]. Let (Y, C) be aw ordered topological vector space with a pointed closed convex cowe C. Then for all x, y 2 Y, we have

(i) y — x 2 intC awd y R intC imply x R intC;

(ii) y — x 2 C awd y R intC imply x R intC;

(iii) y — x 2 —intC awd y R —intC imply x R —intC;

(iv) y — x 2 —C awd y R —intC imply x R —intC.

Definition 2.4 [14]. Consider a subset K of a topological vector space and a topological space Y. A family {(C, Zi)}feI of pair of sets is said to be coercing for a mapping F: K ! 2Y if and only if

(i) for each i 2 I, C,- is contained in a compact convex subset of K and Z, is a compact subset of Y;

(ii) for each i, j 2 I, there exists k 2 I such that C, U C, C Ck;

(iii) for each i 2 I, there exists k 2 I with p| F(x) C Z,-.

Definition 2.5. Let K be a nonempty convex subset of a topological vector space X. A multivalued mapping G : K ! 2X is said to be KKM mapping, if for every finite subset {xi}ieJ of K,

Cofxi : i 2 I} C UF(xi),

where Co{xi : i 2 /} denotes the convex hull of {xi}i£j.

Theorem 2.1 [14]. Let X be a HaMsdorf topological vector space, Y a convex subset of X, K a nonempty subset of Y awd F: K ! 2y a KKM mapping with compactly closed values in Y (i.e., for all x 2 K, F(x) nZ is closed for every compact set Z of Y). f F admits a coercing family, then

\F(x) - £.

Cowdi'ti'ow(C): We say that the cone C satisfies Condition(C), if there is a pointed convex closed cone C such that C \{0} C intC.

3. Existence results

In this section, we prove the following existence results for weak and strong mixed vector equilibrium problems (1.1) and (1.2) for non-compact domain.

Theorem 3.1. Let K be a nonempty closed convex subset of a Hausdorf topological vector space X, Y a Hausdorf topological vector space awd C a closed convex pointed cowe in Y with intC - £. Let f: K x K ! Y awd T: K ! L(X, Y) be two mappings satisfying the following conditions.'

M. Rahaman, R. Ahmad

(i) f is C-monotone;

(ii) f (x, x) — 0, for all x 2 K;

(iii) for any fixed x, y 2 K, t 2 [0,1] # f (ty +(1 — t)x, y) 2 Y is upper semicontinuous with respect to C at t — 0;

(iv) for any fixed x 2 K, f (x, ■) : K ! Y is C-convex, lower semicontinuous with respect to C on K;

(v) T is upper semicontinuous with respect to C with nonempty closed values;

(vi) there exists a family f(Ci, Zt))ieI satisfying conditions (i) and (ii) of Definition 2.4 and the following condition: For each i 2 I, there exists k 2 I such that

fx 2 K: f(y, x) — {T(x), y — x) R intC, 8y 2 Ck) C Zi.

Then, there exists a point x 2 K such that

f(x,y) + {T(x),y — x) R —intC; 8y 2 K.

For the proof of Theorem 3.1, we need the following proposition, for which the assumptions remain same as in Theorem 3.1.

Proposition 3.1. The following two problems are equivalent:

(i) Find x 2 K such that f (y,x) — {T(x),y — xx) R intC;

8y 2 K;

(ii) Find X 2 K such that f (x,y) + {T(x),y — x) R —intC;

8y 2 K.

Proof. Suppose (I) holds. Then for fixed y 2 K, set xt — ty +(1 - t)x, for t 2 [0,1]. It is clear that xt 2 K, for all t 2 [0,1] and hence

f(xt, x) — {T(x), xt — x) R intC. (3-1)

Since f(x, x) — 0 and f(x, ■) is C-convex, we have

0 — f(xt, xt) <c tf(xt, y) + (1 — t)f(xt, x)

) tf(xt, y) + (1 — t)f(xt, x) 2 C. (3.2)

{T(x), xt — x) — t{T(x),y — x) ) (1 — t)t{T(x),y — x)

— (1 — t){T(x), xt — x)—0. (3.3)

Combining (3.2) and (3.3), we obtain

tf(x„y) + (1 — t){f(x„x) — {T(x),x, — x)g + (1 — t)t(T(x),y — x)2 C, (3.4)

for all t 2 [0,1].

Using (3.1) and (3.4) and (ii) of Lemma 2.2, we have

tf(xt,y) + (1 — t)t{T(x),y — x) R —intC ) f(x„y) + (1 — t){T(x),y — x) R —intC,8t 2(0,1]. (3.5)

By condition (iii) of Theorem 3.1 as t # f(ty +(1 — t)x,y) is upper semicontinuous with respect to C at t — 0, therefore from (3.5) we have

f(x,y) + {T(x),y — x) R —intC,

and hence (II) holds.

Conversely, Assume that (II) holds for all y 2 K. In order to prove (I), on contrary suppose that there exists a point y 2 K such that

f(y, x) — {T(x), x — x) 2 intC ) f(y, x)

— {T(x), x — x) + w; (3.6)

for some w 2 intC.

On the other hand, since f is C-monotone, we have

f(x, x)+f(x, x) 2—C ) f(x, x) — —f(x, x) — v; (3.7)

for some v 2 C.

Combining (3.6) and (3.7), we have

f(x,y) + {T(x),x — x) — —w — v 2 —intC; which contradicts assumption (II). Therefore (I) holds. □ Proof of Theorem 3.1. For each y 2 K, consider the set

F(y) — fx 2 K: f(y, x) — {T(x),y — x) R intC).

By Lemma 2.1, F(y) is closed in K and hence F has compactly closed values in K.

Now, we show that F is a KKM map. For this, let {yt : i 2 I) be a finite subset of K and u 2 Co{yi : i 2 I). We claim that

Cofy, : i 2 I) # UF(y,).

In contrary, suppose that u R |J F(y). As u 2 Co{yt : i 2 I), we have u — with k P'0 and Pielkj — 1.

This follows that

f(yi; u) — {T(u), — u)2 intC.

Since intC in convex, therefore

XW(y„ u) — {T(u),y, — u)) 2 intC. (3.8)

Since f(x, ■) is C-convex and C-monotone, we have

^^Ayi; u) ^cYIki XJ)

ieI ijeI

—1 XkW(y-yJ)+f(yJ,yi)} <C 0. (3.9)

2 ij2I Furthermore,

0 — {T(u), u — u) — / T(u),J2 kiyi — ku )

\ i2I i2I I

— / T(u), X k(yi — u)\— X ki{T(u),yt — u). (3.10)

\ i2I I i2I

Combining (3.9) and (3.10), we have

X^T(u)-> yi— u) — Ylkf(yi,'u)2 C

i2I i2I

) X kfy, u) — {T(u), yi — u)) 2 —C. (3.11)

From (3.8) and (3.11), we conclude that

X kf f(y„ u) — {T(u),y, — u)) 2 intC \(—C) — £,

which is a contradiction. This follows that u 2 U F(yt) and

hence Cofyi : i 2 I) # U F(yi). Thus, F is a KKM mapping.

i i2 I i

From the assumption (vi), we can see that the family {(C,,Zi))ieI satisfies the condition which is for all i 2 I, there exists k 2 I such that

HF(y)cZi;

and therefore it is a coercing family for F.

We deduce that F satisfies all the hypothesis of Theorem 2.1. Therefore, we have

\F(y) - £.

Hence, there exists x 2 K such that for any y 2 K

f(y, x) — hT(x,y — x)) R intC.

Now applying Proposition 3.1, we obtain that there exists x 2 K such that for all y 2 K

f(x, y) + {T(x,y — x)) R —intC.

Hence problem (1.1) admits a solution. This completes the proof. □

Corollary 3.1. Let K, C, {(Ci, Zi)}i I, f and T satisfy all the assumptions of Theorem 3.1. In addition, if C satisfies Condition(C), then the problem (1.2) is solvable i.e., there exists x 2 K such that for any y 2 K

f(x,y) + (T(x),y — x) R —(C\{0}).

Proof. Let us suppose that C satisfies Condition(C). Then there is a pointed convex and closed cone C in Y such that

C \{0} C intC:.

Therefore we can easily see that K, C, {(C, Z,-)}i(El, f and T satisfy all the assumptions of Theorem 3.1. Therefore by Theorem 3.1, we get

f(x,y) + (T(x),y — x) R — intC; 8y 2 K. (3.12)

Since —(C \{0}) C — intC, it follows from (3.12) that there exists x 2 K such that

f(x,y) + (T(x),y — x) R —(C \{0}); 8y 2 K.

Hence problem (1.2) admits a solution. This completes the proof. □

References

[1] E. Blum, W. Oettli, From optimization and variational inequalities to equilibrium problems, Math. Students 63 (1994) 123-145.

[2] X.P. Ding, Quasi-equilibrium problems in noncompact generalized convex spaces, Appl. Math. Mech. 21 (6) (2000) 637-644.

[3] F. Giannessi, Vector Variational Inequalities and Vector Equilibria, Kluwer Academic Publishers, Dordrecht, 2000.

[4] A. Moudafi, Mixed equilibrium problems: sensitivity analysis and algorithmic aspects, Comput. Math. Appl. 44 (2002) 10991108.

[5] G.M. Lee, D.S. Kim, B.S. Lee, On non-cooperative vector equilibrium, Indian J. Pure Appl. Math. 27 (1996) 735-739.

[6] M. Bianchi, N. Hadjisavvas, S. Schaible, Vector equilibrium problems with generalized monotone bifunctions, J. Optimiz. Theory Appl. 92 (1997) 527-542.

[7] F. Flores-Bazan, F. Flores-Bazan, Vector equilibrium problems under asymptotic analysis, J. Global Optimiz. 26 (2) (2003) 141166.

[8] J. Fu, Simultaneous vector variational inequalities and vector implicit complementarity problems, J. Optimiz. Theory Appl. 93 (1997) 141-151.

[9] N.X. Tan, P.N. Tinh, On the existence of equilibrium points of vector functions, Numer. Funct. Anal. Optimiz. 19 (1-2) (1998) 141-156.

[10] K. Fan, A minimax inequality and applications, in: O. Shisha (Ed.), Inequalities, New York, USA, vol. 3, 1972, pp. 103-113.

[11] Z. Al-Rumaih, S. Chebbi, H.K. Xu, Non-compact equilibrium points and applications, J. Appl. Math. (2012) 1-9, http:// dx.doi.org/10.1155/2012/373462.

[12] W. Oettli, S. Schlager, Generalized vectorial equilibria and generalized monotonicity, in: M. Brokate, A.H. Siddiqi (Eds.), Functional Analysis with Current Applications, Longman, London, 1997, pp. 145-154.

[13] G.Y. Chen, Existence of solutions for a vector variational inequality: an extension of the Hartmann-Stampacchia theorem, J. Optimiz. Theory Appl. 74 (3) (1992) 445-456.

[14] H. Ben-El-Mechaiekh, S. Chebbi, M. Florenzano, A generalized KKMF principle, J. Math. Anal. Appl. 309 (2) (2005) 583-590.